A Perfect Crime: Inequality in the Age of Globalization Author(s): James K. Galbraith Source: Daedalus, Vol. 131, No. 1, On Inequality (Winter, 2002), pp. 11-25 Published by: The MIT Press on behalf of American Academy of Arts & Sciences Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/20027734 Accessed: 27/10/2009 11:18 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=mitpress. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact
[email protected].
The MIT Press and American Academy of Arts & Sciences are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Daedalus.
http://www.jstor.org
James K. Galbraith A perfect crime: inequality in the age of globalization
of the world's leaders IVlost political economic have embraced globalization on two : that open markets and grounds are transnational networks production unstoppable surely flow
Genoa.
countries, globalization and for imperialism synonym the word evokes colonialism ;generally common rather than collapse gain. All in
of deregulation, all, if the imposition pri free trade, and free capital has in fact raised living stan mobility
;and that the benefits will out to all the world's people,
vatization,
and rich and poor. Leading economists the logic journalists agree, convinced by of laissez-faire, comparative advantage, and technology transfer. Accordingly,
is devilishly dards worldwide, gratitude hard to find. So what are the facts? Has globaliza tion hurt or helped? Oddly, researchers not ask. do not know; mostly they do as it is For the doctrine of globalization
they declare, class conflict and competi tive struggle are obsolete. Yet, outside elite circles, conflict and to disappear. In rich struggle refuse and pressure electorates countries, and proreg groups remain protectionist in parts of Europe ulation, even socialist there iswide sympathy for the (nonvio of and Seattle, Davos, lent) protestors
In poor
is the new
understood
in elite circles
contains
the that the global mar assumption ket is itself beyond reproach. The formu lae for success in that market from curious
;
to sound and transparency openness to investment in education finance remain matters
James K. Galbraith is a professor at theLyndon B. Johnson School of Public Affairs, theUniversity of
Texas
at Austin,
and
a senior
scholar
at the
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College; in the early 1980s, he served as executive director of the congressional Joint Economic Committee. His recent academic work emphasizes practical issues of measurement and data quality as the key to progress on important questions of economic poli cy.His books include "Created Unequal" (1998) and "Inequality and Industrial Change: A Global View" (2001).
of national responsibili countries that fail have only their ty ; own deficiencies to blame. In line with this view, most research has focused on national
conditions and national poli or the cies, and not on global conditions as such. effects of globalization Whether such a national focus is or whether a appropriate, global view a would be better, is question of great we To resolve would it, importance. need new efforts to measure economic and social progress across development countries in effect, around the world
D
dalus
Winter
2002
11
James K. Galbraith on inequality
we would
a global report in this vein, initiatives
to write
need
carcj# gut official theWorld
notably
Bank's Human
Devel
opment Report, are caught in contradic tions between the cheerful predictions of globalization theory and what the evi unem of epidemics, illiteracy, is actu and poverty suggests ployment, that contradictions ally happening have driven several senior figures (most former chief economist famously, Joseph dence
the Stiglitz) out of the Bank. Meanwhile, International Monetary Fund (imf) and World Trade Organization (WTO) are sealed off from today closed societies, most
forms of serious critical discussion. can independent research con what So, of the state tribute to an understanding of the global economy today? Not much, evi the fragmentary perhaps, beyond dence of case studies and field reports. usually lack new bring together on a information scale. global Still, one broader area has attracted attention: economic inequality and its
Truly independent to the resources
scholars
to economic In this growth. relationship as we shall see area, data (collated, below, from many sources) independent are already available. A rich (but inex can be to econometrics brought pensive) on the findings. hinges economic and inequality
bear. And much
For, while are hardly the only issues in growth litera world development life, health, are more the and cy, peace important these between relationship perceived two economic opment
policy
variables
underlies
in profound
devel
ways.
economist Simon -L/ong ago, the great to Kuznets linked (1901 -1985) equality ar Kuznets the development process. as industrialization began, it gued that at lead to an increasing inequality might first: would
the rough parity among farmers an emerging urban give way to 12 D
dalus
Winter
2002
But as industrialization
rural divide.
the center
of economic gravi shift to the cities. To live in
deepened, ty would
cities, to work for wages, requires free labor and that every family have some access to cash. The larger the share of basic consumption goods provided the more equal through the marketplace, incomes must become. Eventual money and social-welfare systems ly, democracy would toward the emerge ;progress social democratic of West frameworks ern was a and North America Europe as well as an ideal. pragmatic possibility Kuznets offered an optimistic vision, to that of John Maynard Keynes more austere in though style. Properly could be civi development managed, similar
lead to the misery and that Karl Marx had earlier fore upheaval seen. But in recent years, as the Marxian lized;
it need not
threat disappeared, Kuznets's vision also unions in disorder and receded. With welfare
states
in disrepute, the 'Kuznets serves mainly as a
now
hypothesis' research whipping boy of development at length, ers, to be raised, sometimes as discon but usually to be dismissed tinued by modern data, generally by economists who see no contradiction
between and development. inequality In a 1993 report entitled the East Asian to as EAM), Miracle referred (hereafter economists
at the World
Bank offered
an
alternative
theory. They argued that of land redistributions, early especially were precondi and primary schooling, tions for industrial
success
in Japan, Ko
rea, Taiwan, China, and Thailand. This widely cation
Singapore, Malaysia, argument has been a case for edu cited to underpin as a development tool, to support
in the early stages, redistributive policies to argue that development and especially can be market-friendly, the provided in and "right" pattern of endowments centives
exists
at the outset.
pre By emphasizing market-friendly conditions for growth, the EAM team undermined the presumption that devel and rising equality normally - even together though the Asian evidence did suggest that this was in fact the case inmost places. The team also the policy activism of many downplayed Asian states, especially their commit ments to planning, industrial policy, opment occur
financial
control, and the development - all cornerstones of social welfare of a as normal development under process stood by Keynes
and Kuznets
in their
day. The EAM's striking hypothesis also to in called attention, the indirectly, of in about information completeness around
the world. While efforts to measure
equality had been many at the national equalities
there in
level, no one measurements to had brought those a gether in single global data set. As a one result, it remained unclear whether
could generalize perience. Were valid on awider
from
the East Asian
the apparent scale ?Was
that redistributive
policies
ex
lessons it really true set the stage
for growth? To help answer
that question, Klaus and of the World Deininger Lyn Squire to mine Bank decided the economic de literature for surveys of in velopment come of thousands inequality. Finding in scores of studies, such measures they evaluated each data point on three crite ria. Did the study focus on households, rather than persons ?Did it attempt to measure all forms of income, including in-kind incomes ? Did it attempt to cov er all parts of the society, including rural as well as urban areas ? In 1996 re they the data these three published satisfying criteria as a "high-quality" data set on income inequality household since 1950. The Deininger-Squire data set is now a standard
reference
;a recent version
of
A perfect cnme
fers nearly 750 country/year observations on which dozens of papers have been based. The
an unintended
result has been
scent
into confusion.
As
de
scholars
sought in between relationships in and the equality, income, growth World Bank's data, no consistent pat tern emerged. Some seemed to confirm systematic
the Kuznets
Others hypothesis. argued that inequality first falls and then rises with rising income :the oppo instead
a rela finding of low inequality and first supported, and on the that the ground seemed to rest on conti
site pattern. The tionship between later growth was then questioned,
EAM
relationship differences nent-specific America and Asia. Meanwhile, came under associated servative
Latin
between
viewpoints pro-equality from a quarter
challenge, with older
policy
views.
theories
and con
In Victorian was
nomic
eco
itself the
thought, inequality spur of growth. Growth required capital and itwas the accumula accumulation, tions made possible by concentrating incomes that justified an unequal class structure. The Victorian system worked - so in practice, well enough as, long occur did and the class growth working es enjoyed the benefit of a steadily rising living standard. But, as Keynes particu all this had died larly well understood, with World War I. And then, after sixty years, the very same idea was born again. Let the rich - so wrote econo rule the supply-side mists who came to power behind Ron in America ald Reagan and Margaret Thatcher in Britain. Tax cuts would
im
the incentives
to of the wealthy prove and invest." High interest "work, save, rates would reward saving and quash inflation. And a fetish of the entrepre neur ness
and busi spread through political that implicitly culture, a doctrine D
dalus
Winter
2002
13
James K. Galbraith on
inequality
the concept of value in innova t^on an(j ieacjership, rather than in labor . . r i i or consumers. or even in the happiness rooted
a similar doctrine finds expres Today, sion in models that emphasize syner returns, technological increasing in part Two good educations, are more than twice as good as nership, gies,
change.
should concentrate one, so the educated into enclaves. Technical development of the the relative productivity the skilled well trained therefore, pay more and the unskilled less. In these as clusters cases, inequalities expressed will foster of privileged opportunity raises
more
rapid growth. an empirical basis for such Seeking Kristin Forbes uses the Dein claims, and inger Squire data set to find that in are followed by in creases in inequality creased growth rates. If valid, these find reverse
the EAM idea without
lost luster
to Simon Kuznets.1
ings would restoring
matters have i\s stand, economists four different possibilities, broached for the each with different implications : economic of strategy development The redistributionist view holds that egal are a precondition itarian social policies for growth and points to the Asian mira cle before the crash of 1997 as prime land This view emphasizes but tends to resist and education, once inmarket processes intervention have been successfully preconditions
Inequality may well rise, but the of a growth strategy makes the sacrifice worthwhile.
change. success
The Kuznets and Keynes view implies that is the normal out increasing equality come of a process of rising incomes whether fast or slow and that social are normal welfare policies outgrowths to an urban industrial of the transition This perspective that redistribution
economy.
suppose cede growth equality will
; it only decline
matures.
process
not pre
does
should
pre implies that in as the development
But if Kuznets
and
were
Keynes right, then strategies of im industrial diversification, planning, financial and substitution, control, port state are a legitimate part of the welfare tool kit; they do not the development contradict the fundamental project. is The Scotch verdict "not proven" to that development be unrelated may in any inequalities is This the fallback posi systematic way. tion of some who argue for growth as the sole development objective. and economic
social
is complex. Many could be true. But how
the world
Plainly, different
things of these four conflicting
many ses
are,
correct?
actually,
At
hypothe one.2
most,
one ?A great deal rides on the
Which answer.
evidence. reform
met.
The should sources
ports,
neoliberal view is that policymakers re go for growth, concentrating on
comparative
and the fostering
advantage,
ex
of technological
v_>Jne reason why the question is that the evidence unresolved
2 To
see
14 D
dalus
Winter
2002
the
contradiction
hypothesis consider hypothesis, identical levels with If both
i See Kristin of the "A Reassessment Forbes, and Growth," Between Relationship Inequality Review American Economic 90 (3) (September 869-887. 2000):
against have been test - is data set
views which the modern ed the Deininger-Squire unreliable.
Kuznets
then Kuznets
both.
But
country inequality
the
of
income
and
start
inequality.
income level, higher in decline should inequality
the Forbes can
between
and, say, the Forbes two countries that
to a
grow
under
remains
raise in the
model
its growth short run.
suggests rate by It follows
that
one
increasing that later
cannot
One
-
are
measurements
sparse,
Africa, West Asia, and Latin America. And where observations exist, they are : falls for about questionable inequality in this exercise, in a half the countries decade marked by wide protests against data and com rising inequality! When mon perception clash so sharply, which
sepa
rated in time by many years or even dec some of the rank ades. Second, while - one seem reasonable expect ings might low inequality readings from Eastern years Europe during the communist others are, to put itmildly, implausible.
is to be believed?
in India, Pakistan, and In Is inequality donesia really in the same general league as in Norway? in Spain Is inequality Is inequali really lower than in France? in Australia the States and United ty or the to, say, Nigeria comparable really Sudan? It is doubtful that any Sudanese thinks so.
One
on
that
country
will income
higher
have, and
other
things
at least
equal,
the EAM model reducing
is correct,
inequality
in the
a country run will
then short
across
income
case,
if growth
level then
as one
that
the
transition,
and
it may
be
be measured
growth
specify what accelerates.
happens
to
inequality
easily and accurately countries. Pay is, of course,
if
many
for a large
be
In this
re
stored at all ; the EAM hypothesis does not clearly
countries.
of house Inequalities widely neglected. hold income the focus of Deininger - are to meas and Squire very difficult we measurements and the do have ure, come from unofficial often surveys.3 Levels of pay, on the other hand, may
be re may be observed not
per
so turns out to be possible, long to narrow the focus and iswilling to return to official sources of informa - sources tion that are very rich, but
in the redistrib
accelerates
the Kuznets country, pattern uting not stored after a time. But it will during
not.
does
basis,
year-to-year
This as one
observed at lower inequality but initially the same
a
of changes mitting comparison to changes in inequality in GDP. It should be based on data that are reason consistent ably accurate and reasonably
being or per
The downward-sloping haps higher, inequality. no relation Kuznets will longer be observed, in time series or panel either data. Similarly,
on
detailed
is rapidly reduced to a data set are from half of all observations
equal,
V Ve clearly need more and better data. A new data set should, ideally, approach coverage of the global comprehensive economy
these re The thin coverage on which amore serious sults are based becomes one tries to compute still when problem in theWorld Bank's inequality changes time period. data over some consistent where
of the
for Economic
Cooperation (this is true of the Forbes study, for example). A simple effort to compare changes from the the decades for 1980s to the 1990s which the Bank reports the most obser vations shows no data for most of Organization and Development
data set quickly reveals "high-quality" fundamental problems. in First, in many parts of the world Africa most of all, but also in Latin America, Asia, and even in parts of Eu rope
countries
the affluent member
but admire the effort of some or and Deininger Squire to bring der to the chaotic history of income-in Still, a compari equality measurement. son of coefficient values from their
3 The only consistent formal definition of comes
have
from
the
income
tax,
It is tax
the precise allowable specifies of each type of inflow and outflow. law that specifies and that wages
code
salaries
are
treatment
not, after
we
income whose
should vary,
that
but
income,
and
be deducted, the
are gifts received of business expenses
that
reimbursements
of
concept
D
so on.
income
dalus
Winter
Since
tax
is therefore
2002
laws nation
15
A perfect cnme
James K. Galbraith inequality
of income. Levels of manufactur - an subset of all pay important ingpay have been measured with reasonable a as matter of official routine in accuracy subset
most
countries
around
the world
for data nearly resulting sector have payrolls by manufacturing indus been placed in a single systematic trial accounting framework by the Unit forty years. The
ed Nations
International
Development which makes
(UNIDO),
Organization
both
cross-country comparison relatively reliable. if one
In short,
easy and
into focus.4 of the University of has been (UTIP) Inequality Project to compute consistent measures of man contribution
Texas
this
from
pay inequality
ufacturing
set permits us to generate large of inequality measures that can across countries be compared and data
numbers
through time. The year 2000 release of the UNIDO data set alone contains suffi cient information for nearly 3,200 coun between 1963 and try/year observations than four times the coverage 1998 more of Deininger and Squire.
to look at the
iswilling
relationship through growth-inequality the narrow lens of pay rates and earnings to get the picture it is possible structures,
xhe
an using inequality metric in the 1960s by the late econo developed metrician Henri Theil.5 The application to UNIDO's of this technique industrial information,
main
4 The siveness
trade-off
measurement
are
conventions
of
effects
trade,
accounting laws. Differences across
ments
in measured
tax
in accounting and countries will produce In countries
incomes.
treat
differences
where
sub
or are unrecorded, parts of income or hidden in kind, from delivered tax, or where are vague, of standards accounting problems valuation and aggregation rapidly mount. stantial
is no
be
reason
to to expect measurements time or across surveys. through the project of comparing facts make across countries and years inequality
There
consistent
These income
and difficult, doubly at moderately reliable meticulous
even
in practice
comparisons of micro-level
examination
to arrive requires data.
Such a project has been undertaken with in recent Studies, wealthiest
countries. on
researchers,
The World
the other
their
of data judgments about work information
tury
in far-flung
surveys. pendent is not their fault are
coefficients
l6 D
quality done
to the Bank's had
hand,
on over
to base summary a half cen
often inde locales, through and It cannot be surprising that the resulting inequality
dalus
Winter
2002
the
the broader which
distribution, effects
of
and
taxes, Second,
composition. a strong correla apparent our measures of manufacturing
changing there is nevertheless tion
of concept includes
transfers,
household
between
pay inequality and the (we believe, reliable)
but inequality reported of countries range only by the Income This Studies. is, of course, Luxembourg : countries with highly plausible strongly egali are com to have both tarian values likely and strong welfare pay structures pressed
measures
of
income
for a limited
states.
we
Thus
a very
provides mate rankings
believe
that
the UTIP way
inexpensive of income
to
inequality and reliable
where detailed countries, data are not available.
5 To
be precise,
we
groups component a set of industrial two-
to
three-digit
compute of Theil's
approach approxi for many micro
inequality entropy mation
the between T
statistic
categories, generally standard international
industrial classification statistic
desirable
problematic.
than
income
skill
Income
years by the Luxembourg but it is restricted mainly
itself,
hypothesis of pay, rather
confounding tax
and the change, concern the distribu
technological
Kuznets tion
in the
codified
comprehen accurate
emphasize
manufactur domain, over measure ing pay inequality, implausible ment of a comprehensive income one, inequali pay inequalities ty. However, manufacturing are in their own interesting right. First, many economic the important problems, particularly
household
ally specific,well defined only where precise
is between
: we accuracy of a limited
and
(isic)
across at the
levels. Theil's T
of a class example as "generalized on infor based measures," originally measures have all the Such theory. is the best-known measures
mathematical
known
characteristics
of
the
of
A map averaging values of an inequali from these data ty coefficient computed
(see figure 1) graphically displays the key as findings. Over the 1963 -1998 period, these data reveal, manufacturing pay in was lowest in the social democ equality racies of Scandinavia and in Australia the communist
and under
regimes of and Cuba (be changes, data for
Eastern
Europe, China cause of the boundary Russia here exclude the Soviet
years). Southern Europe and North America form a second group of countries with
low levels of pay inequality. relatively countries The wealthier of Latin Ameri ca (such as Argentina, and Venezuela, and West Asia (Iran) form a Colombia) middle group; Russia (after 1991) and
South Africa rank slightly higher. The are found regions of highest inequality a in broad equatorial belt, from Peru and Brazil through central Africa and south ern Asia, the largest gaps be reflecting tween city and countryside, between oil more
Gini known widely are additive addition they that inequality (meaning
plus total
inequality
between
and
coefficient,
in
and
decomposable a set of groups within sums to the groups
for the combined inequality population). This makes tool for work them a very flexible data, and we have ing with semi-aggregated meas in that changes shown between-group ures are often a very robust of indicator
changes in the whole distribution the unobserved Use
of
es of
industrial international
innovation cussion technical Maureen
within-groups
of of
category
comparison the UTIP project.
technical
(including
component). for purpos schemes
appendices Berner, eds.,
Inequality
the and
and Industrial
Change (Cambridge :Cambridge University I thank 2001). sub Kum, and George
Press,
Pedro Purcell
Concei?ao, especially,
Hyun from
among the UTIP team, for diligent help with and with calculations ; the present concepts world data set in particular is Kum's handi are at The UTIP measurements work.
://utip.gov.utexas.edu>.
A perfect cnme
tion tend to go hand in hand. the Kuznets hypothesis Although to levels of levels of inequality relating or is income corroborated pay broadly some doubts about his by these findings, views
do remain.
example, Kuznets
It is debatable, for if inequality must increase,
as
in the earliest
stages Yet that so far places, as modern times and data are con are past the ear cerned: most countries
supposed, of industrial development. ismoot inmost question
ly stages. Itmay also be that inequality rises slightly in a few of the very richest as income grows, due countries partly to - a sectors in capital gains technology pattern of interest for students of the United States and the United Kingdom, but not broadly relevant to the study of economic development. On
is the principal For further dis
consult details, please in James K. Galbraith
and food, and the weakest development and the producof mass manufacturing tion of capital goods. are in These findings striking accord with Kuznets's basic hypothesis. Higher are incomes and lower pay inequality is Because associated. this true, strongly there is no reason to expect a systematic between relationship today inequality and growth later, and none can be found. Redistribution in either direc or not a tion is down up apparently economic for ; in precondition growth and redistribu stead, successful growth
within
the whole,
of pay inequalities to tend be lower manufacturing
in rich countries than in poor. That means that inequality almost surely de clines as industrialization and deepens as incomes rise. This is consis finding tent over the globe, with limited excep run of an tions, over a thirty-five-year in the early 1960s. nual data, beginning that Kuznets's -Besides confirming view of the relationship between growth remains basically and inequality correct, D
dalus
Winter
2002
17
James
K.
Galbraith inequality
i
Figure
Global Inequality 1963
-
1997 of manufac
Inequality
turing pay computed by the University of Texas from Inequality Project 2000 edition the UNIDO of Industrial
Statistics over 1963 and averaged ranked 1997 ; countries
as in six quantiles the high 3. Note and geographic coverage into
Figure
of inequality consistency in the OECD patterns and across the develop for ing regions. Data are
Russia only start
; those
post-Soviet for China
in 1979. Data the Czech Republic,
1
for
3 0.036-0.052 4 D 0.052-0.074
and the post Slovakia, states begin Yugoslav with the formation of those
states
in the
Least
inequality
Germany Netherlands Poland
0.002510 0.002604 0.002916 0.004644 0.005988 0.006639 0.007344 0.007539 0.008529 0.009058 0.009170 0.009634 0.010957 0.011076 0.011777 0.012012
Luxembourg Hong Kong Hungary Slovakia Malta Britain Taiwan Slovenia France Austria
0.013181 0.013624 0.014684 0.015137 0.015548 0.015610 0.015858 0.016014 0.016278 0.017799
Cape Verde Latvia Cuba Sweden Czech Republic Denmark Seychelles Romania Macau Norway Australia Finland
dalus
Winter
i^^^^^^^^B^^*. ^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^B| ^HF ^^
5 I 0.074-0.099 i^^fl^^^Hr 6 H 0.099 -0.893, most inequality ? No data available ISB^^Kr
1990s.
China
l8 D
(Theil Inequality <=O.Ol8,
Canada Bulgaria Italy Algeria Croatia Nicaragua Afghanistan New Zealand Ireland Belgium United States Mexico Iceland Bangladesh South Korea Ethiopia Egypt Bosnia & Herz. Iraq Japan Namibia Moldavia Spain Malaysia Ukraine Greece
2002
0.018428 0.019515 0.019734 0.020126 0.020982 0.022988 0.023208 0.025219 0.025589 0.025629 0.025646 0.027479 0.028083 0.028631 0.028825 0.029650 0.029919 0.030493 0.030966 0.031031 0.031425 0.031845 0.033788 0.034413 0.034697 0.035561
^^^^^^^v ^^^^^^?
^^^^^^^?^
^#^?ff|5f Gambia Colombia Burkina Faso
Azerbaijan Costa Rica Portugal Nigeria Libya Turkey Iran Burma Senegal Madagascar Cyprus Macedonia Israel
Fiji Ecuador North Yemen Pakistan Uruguay Argentina Sudan Somalia El Salvador Venezuela
0.037424 0.037912 0.038420 0.038456 0.038469 0.039110 0.040251 0.040600 0.040697 0.040782 0.041626 0.042025 0.042821 0.043173 0.043215 0.044112 0.045027 0.045361 0.045504 0.045698 0.045894 0.048402 0.048610 0.048952 0.051577 0.051952
~*** s"^^
*&t--
A perfect
' "5*s=^^_
crime
Most
4 Haiti Zimbabwe Botswana Sri Lanka
0.052814 0.054305 0.055032 0.056491 0.058459 0.058507 0.058517 0.058699 0.061265 0.061392 0.061593 0.061596 0.062061
Singapore Chile Russia South Africa Zambia Tonga Neth. Antilles Philippines Suriname Panama Barbados Ivory Coast Syria Cen. African Bolivia Nepal Am. Samoa U. Arab Emir. Mauritius Eritrea Albania
Rep.
0.062894 0.063116 0.064147 0.065215 0.066105 0.066374 0.068082 0.069093 0.069918 0.071762 0.072629 0.073632
Benin India Yugoslavia Brazil Rwanda Domincan Tanzania Lithuania Tunisia Burundi
Rep.
Jordan Peru Indonesia Kyrgystan Liberia Morocco Kenya Togo Papua N. Guinea Honduras Eq. Guinea Mauritania Thailand Bhutan Malawi Guatemala Bahamas
inequality
Lesotho Belize Gabon Swaziland Armenia South Yemen
0.074386 0.075959 0.076278 0.077607 0.078161 0.079278 0.079455 0.080079 0.080430 0.082687 0.082940 0.082944 0.084083 0.085131 0.085607 0.085982 0.086183 0.086519 0.086716 0.086866
0.105516 0.105935 0.106911 0.106922 0.108136 0.109596 0.109652 0.113724 0.118893 0.121705 0.129300 0.136999 0.145823 0.149679 0.184693 0.188703 0.194245 0.201428 0.206362 0.230317 0.253880 0.312738 0.403546 0.404105 0.442336 0.892605
Uganda Oman Ghana Puerto Rico Cameroon Congo Trinidad
& Tobago Mozambique Saudi Arabia Niger St. Vincent
& Gren.
Angola Cambodia Kuwait Sierra Leone
0.089228 0.092261 0.094014 0.095370 0.095639 0.097286 0.098721
Jamaica Bahrain Qatar Mongolia Paraguay
D
dalus
Winter
2002
19
Figure 2 A regression income and
James K.
Galbraith on inequality
on of inequality time, UTIP data a reflects regression
set. The
sloping Kuznets as a as well global
downward relation toward
drift
sharply higher inequali time. (Color scales have
ty over a similar
but are not gradient to previous graphs.)
matched
o.?
&*
Year 63
65
67
69
71
73
75
77
79
81
83
85
87
89
91
93
97
95
O.OO -0.05 11
-O.lO
I ?
-0.201
UUilU
-o.30?J? -0.35
IMI|||
-0.40
Figure Panel
5 estimates
of the world
of rising in for coun controlling effects the ef and try-specific in per capita re fect of changes of al income levels. The method
wide
time pattern
equality,
panel lation
estimates
permits of a year-to-year
in changing
20 D
dalus
Winter
2002
inequality.
calcu pattern
A perfect crime
1981 to 1987 Change -42.4 to -1.09 -1.09 to 0.65
?
to 3.42 3.42 to 9.14 9.14 to 24.74 [~] N.A. 0.65
S
/
s (above) in the Age of Debt. in inequality from 1981 Changes to 1987. Dark gray indicates the
Figure 4 (below)
Figure
Inequality
in largest increases (notably Latin America and among oil at this time of col producers ;blue indi lapsing oil prices) cates declines ; light gray is "neutral."
Almost
the only
cas
ed from
Patterns
of rising inequality the age of globalization. in inequality from Changes
the global financial sys tem (China, India, Iran). Greece and Turkey showed very large increases their con following over in the frontation Cyprus 1970s may
;declines be a return
1988 to 1994. The rise is extreme. The only
in the
including policy the end of military
in Russia significant
is region of declining inequality in the boom countries of South - more east Asia evidence of
1980s to normality, in Greece after
the Kuznets
rule.
effect.
es of in this declining inequality are in countries insulat period
n ?
1.77to 5.5 5-5 to 11.82 %. 11.82 to 78.83 N.A.
in
* Wr (f'
D
dalus
Winter
2002
21
James K. Galbraith inequality
the UTIP data also permit us to detect in changes of inequality, global patterns to take a fresh look at the New World
of the oil slump that followed. During rises most that time, inequality rapidly cone of Latin America in the Southern
Order.
East. Second, and in parts of the Middle there was the collapse (in part induced, as in and Poland, by intract Yugoslavia able debts) of the communist world; the focus of ris these countries become
This result.
exercise For when
lated, we find
a
produces disquieting the global trend is iso that in the last two de
cades, inequality has increased through out the world in a pattern that cuts across the effect of national income
in the late 1980s. By the ing inequalities as mid-1990s, figure 4 reveals, almost the countries with declining inequality only were the countries of Southern booming Asia (even if the crash after 1997 almost
the decades that hap changes. During pen to coincide with the rise of neoliber of al ideology, with the breakdown and with the end sovereignties, in the global debt of Keynesian policies rose crisis of the early 1980s, inequality curve In effect, the Kuznets worldwide. national
to income shifted inequality the upward slope This finding upward. of the plane in figure 2 points to influ ences on of a global order. inequality that there is a common The finding global upward trend in inequality pro for one of two vides strong evidence relating
raised inequality independ universally ent of income changes but for what itmay be that reason? Alternatively, economic alone do not national policies and cannot entirely control national pay and that there is a common, structures, global
element
rested their hopes fifty years ago. Keynes Even so, the figures do not fully capture
(though they do reflect) the deepening ex whose dissolution of nation-states, treme cases lead to war, as in Bosnia, the eastern Croatia, Kosovo, Macedonia,
is that na One possibility propositions. almost have tional economic policies
pernicious,
some of them in another surely took direction). - as as any This pattern shows clearly one indicator to do the ser might hope ial failure of the global development to permit the build process as awhole democracies advanced of industrial ing states on which Kuznets and welfare and
Aceh, southern Co Congo, Chechnya, even all of them and lombia, Chiapas of their the among parent poorest parts states. But as inequality deepens, more of this is surely on the way.
in the global passed out of fashion, fallen into have generally two camps :those who believe that redis on the one tribution fosters growth, hand, and those who believe on the con
Oince
economy.
In the latter case we have
to ask, what some Is there, perhaps, is that element? laissez the of process global thing about faire itself
that created
this outcome
?
if so, is it an inherent feature of Or is it only an artifact "globalization?" of the particular policies under which
And
the global market recent years?
has been
liberalized
3 and 4 illustrate the regional of patterns increasing inequality during two key episodes. First, there was the early 1980s, the years of debt crisis and Figures
22 D
dalus
Winter
2002
Kuznets
economists
in
is a price trary that rising inequality These worth paying for development. statements national about are, however, UTIP with the data conditions. Working a set to isolate different set, it is possible in of factors :those factors that co-evolve the world
economy through of the movement
pendently income. The
annual
pattern
time, inde of national of these
time effects, presented in figure 5, gives us an essential so clue far lacking: the at which
precise turning point in inequality element and started to rise.6
ceased
Nor
the global
As figure 5 shows, the common global in pay inequalities declines element slightly through the late 1970s. It then turns around in 1981 -1982, just as Ron
the of real interest rates brought latter from near o to 5 percent or higher for completely riskless assets and much higher for most countries with currencies. The result was depreciating a to precipitate global debt crisis in the course of which many poorer nations were forced first to cut imports and capi climate
to
fare policies. The years since 1980 have test of the second thus seen an empirical an of view: system point extraordinary, atic increase in inequality. It has not followed by any increase in the glo bal rate of economic expansion. For a cause of worldwide rising in one must to events look that equality, been
not before.
the period after 1980, but of trade will not do. Growth
Worldwide
trade grew very rapidly " the devel through period of stabilizing (the Mexican term) that began opment" in 1945 and ended in the 1970s ; it is not a af peculiar feature of the environment ter
1980.
6 Our fects
technique data
panel
here
is a two-way which
estimation,
fixed entails
ef
estimates
common
course
economy income
over
ed
changes. in figure 5
of of
the
time
dummies
reveal
in the global for controlling
inequality
the years, The time
effects
are present
1970s, long before the personal comput er revolution. And after 1980, inequality rises more sharply in poorer countries, where of course new technologies a spread the least. In country like Fin land, a leader
in Internet penetration, rose at all. inequality hardly can a sequence of events What explain that affects an almost universal spec trum of poorer countries after 1980, ex cluding only India and China in that de eco cade and a handful of the booming nomies of South Asia in the 1990s? The evidence of timing points toward the effect of rising real interest rates and the debt crisis. For this, the stage was set in 1973 of the Bretton by the dissolution Woods
framework
of fixed-but-adjust rates and international
able exchange
of capital flow. As figure 5 supervision framework shows, the collapse ofthat ended a period of relatively stable structures. and stable pay growth a short There then followed period of the oil and commodities
boom, with commer fueled declining inequality by cial debt. But this was unsustainable, and it came to a crashing end in the worldwide financial shock that was ini in 1980 -1981 by the United States, as the U.S. Federal Reserve interest rates past 20 pushed nominal tiated
cre
for each country and variables ating "dummy" The coefficient estimates year in the sample. on the dummies the pat then reveal country tern of national while the coeffi institutions, cient
A perfect cnme
ty in theUnited States beginning in the
ald Reagan took office in the United States. At this time, a shift in the global
characterize
technological accelerating change explain the pattern. The story case is often hinted at for the American that the rapid spread of computers after "skill-biased 1980 made technological a change" driving force behind rising But the UTIP (and all pay differentials. data other) clearly show rising inequali
declining
and then were pressured tal spending, abandon trade and wel long-standing
can
the
percent. The rise in interest rates pro cuts in duced dramatic and continuing with results for the imports, devastating of poorer coun prospects development tries. Many
of them have never
recov
ered.
D
dalus
Winter
2002
23
James K. Galbraith on
inequality
Indeed, matters were made worse by the concurrent triumphr of neoliberal ism in the United
Russia
States and the United same years. Following the rich countries
was
chitecture
created
from
ar
the wreck
control.
It is not,
that the then, by accident at a global level of neoliberalism resemble those of a coup d'?tat at a
effects
national In an
investors.
in Latin honing these policies were after America, 1989 in they applied After
before,
during, : the case
coups the general pat chart on the bot
and
tern. The tom
level.
early analysis using UTlP's set, George Purcell and I calculated
data the
6
Inequality and after Chile
in
and then
in China, in Northern notably Europe, and in the United States itself after the did growth continue and mid-1990s remain reasonable under pay inequality
banks. In age left by the commercial Fund stead, the International Monetary and then financial preached austerity, and privatization sale of deregulation state assets at fire-sale prices to foreign
Figure
Europe,
crisis ensued. Only where Everywhere, countries resisted the neo successfully - most liberal policy prescriptions
in these
Kingdom the debt crisis, the "magic of the market preached place" to the poor. No new financial
and Eastern
Asia.
averages
the change for up to five
Inequality in Chile 300
of
o o
of
years up to five years after a coup d'?tat ; the aver across twen age is calculated cases. historical ty-seven
inequality before and
s;
200 150
50
63 65 67 69
71 73 75 77 79 81 83
85 87 89 91 93 95
Year
Change in Inequality: 27 Coups D'Etat
I I I 1before 1 after 3 before 3 after 5 after 2 before 2 after 4 before 4 after Coup year
$before
24 D
dalus
Winter
2002
coups average effects of twenty-seven of pay in d'?tat on our measurements a pattern of equality. We found striking After consistency. rising four and five years before the coup, inequality would decline sharply in the two years immedi In the year of the coup ately beforehand. in inequality would itself, the decline stop. And in the five repressive years that followed from (coups, as distinct are almost revolutions, invariably right occur sys rising inequality would wing), in each year, until overall tematically stood far higher than in the inequality before the coup. Figure 6 presents period case of Chile our data for the canonical and the curve that emerges from averag cases. ing effects over the twenty-seven Viewed
from a global perspective, the of time effects observed world
pattern wide after 1975 strongly resembles this curve. Global characteristic inequality
fell in the late 1970s. In those years, poor countries had the benefit of low interest
trade as such In sum, it is not increasing we that should fear. Nor is technology the culprit. To focus on "globalization" as such misstates the issue. The problem is a process of integration carried out since at least 1980 under circumstances in which of unsustainable finance, has flowed upwards from the to the rich, and mainly to poor countries strata of the richest the upper financial
wealth
countries.
In the course toward
tolerable
of these events, progress levels of inequality and
sustainable
virtually development Neocolonial patterns of center
stopped. and of debt dependence, periphery were but with reestablished, peonage, out the slightest assumption of responsi for the fate of bility by the rich countries the poor. It has been,
itwould appear, a perfect crime. And while statistical forensics can a small role in this out, play pointing no mechanism to reverse the policy
rates and easy credit,
and high commod for oil. Indeed, in ity prices, especially the 1970s, the UTIP data shows that it was the lower-income in the workers
still less any that might repair the countries have damage. The developed the pretense abandoned of attempting to foster development in the world at
countries who made the largest in But in 1980 -1981, the age of pay. gains low interest rates and high commodity
to substitute the rheto large, preferring ric of ungoverned for the hard markets work of stabilizing The prog regulation. nosis is grim :a descent into apathy, disaster, and despair, disease, ecological wars of separatism and survival in many
poorer
prices ended. - a In 1982, the repression took hold to be sure, but not financial repression, less real for having taken that form. And the debt crisis was not accompa nied by overt violence coups are, in in their overt often limited deed, very violence the effects were soon felt
while
and with a savage intensity worldwide, that has continued for two decades.
A perfect crime
exists,
of the poorest parts of the world. of course, the wise spirits of Unless, Kuznets and Keynes can be summoned back to life, to deal more constructively with the appalling disorder of the past twenty years.
D
dalus
Winter
2002
25