Wp2 Revised

  • June 2020
  • PDF

This document was uploaded by user and they confirmed that they have the permission to share it. If you are author or own the copyright of this book, please report to us by using this DMCA report form. Report DMCA


Overview

Download & View Wp2 Revised as PDF for free.

More details

  • Words: 1,386
  • Pages: 5
How Economists Write on The Dismal Science The dismal science, a term coined by Scottish historian, Thomas Carlyle, in the 19th century is used to describe the depressing and dreary nature of the field of economics. This name was given to economics as economics aims to answer questions like why some people are poor while others are rich, how a country can go from being prosperous to struggling with mass poverty and starvation in less than a decade, etc. It is up to economists to analyze data, experiment with theories, and develop models to lead closer to a hopefully less dismal explanation for these phenomena. A phenomenon that has caught the interest of economists worldwide is the financial crisis of 2007-2008. Economists, eager to know the ins and outs of the causes, effects, and solutions that got the United States economy out of the recession, got to rigorous study and research. As a product, many economists presented their own theories and ideas concerning the economic collapse in academic essays, articles, and books. Examples of these academic writings are “Economic Stagnation Postponed: Background of the 2008 Financial-Economic Crisis in the European Union and the United States”, “The Financial Crisis: Lessons for International Macroeconomics”, and “Hedge Funds and the Financial Crisis of 2007–2008”. These writings on the financial crisis serve the purpose of answering the questions surrounding the recession by using a standard format, fieldspecific lexicon, and makes claims backed by data and evidence. When reading academic articles, you’ll notice an adherence to a common format that acts to uniform entries; economists’ academic articles are no exception to this. All three of the articles presented have titles that serve the purpose of informing the reader exactly the reason for the article as they are often straightforward to avoid vagueness and confusion. Reuten and Bussière et al. utilize subtitles to achieve this straightforwardness and use the main title to act as a hook. However,

Gutierrez 1 this hook can only be so vague and or creative as to not cause confusion or contradiction with the subtitle. Following the titles in economists’ academic articles is an abstract which serves a similar purpose as the title. The abstract informs the reader on what the article is about contains the authors’s claim. Throughout the rest of these articles, the use of figures and data cited in APA style are used as evidence to support the claim found in the abstract. Although APA style is very common, it is not always used in economists’ academic articles. Like a discourse community, academics in the field of economics use terms, phrases, and concepts unfamiliar to those outside the field. This lexicon, specific to economics, is used by authors because it allows them to be most effective in their writing. In a sense, they are able to assume knowledge in their readers to make shortcuts in their writings. Considering that economists’ academic articles are written mainly for others in the field it is understood why such verbiage is used that is unknown or confusing to common readers. For example, when Dixon explains one of the root causes of the financial crisis, he writes “Bear Stearns bought subsidiaries that made subprime mortgages directly to home buyers and set up two internal hedge funds that loaded up on MBSs and CDOs. The Bear Stearns funds were leveraged 10 or 15 to 1 and targeted assets that were rated AA or AAA.” Dixon’s explanation is chock-full of field-specific terminology, MBSs, CDOs, and the ratings that rating agencies use, that the average reader wouldn’t know and doesn’t later explain these terms. Dixon and other academics knowingly do this because they know the genre they are writing in and so does their intended audience. When economists write, a lot of the freedom and direction in their writings comes from and is influenced by the audience they are writing for. Economists write to share their own theories and evidence but to also create dialogue and elicit responses from their readers. To promote this purpose, it is very easy for other authors in the audience to cite and reference these articles due to

Gutierrez 2 the presence of database markers. Whether it’s an ISSN for printed entries or a DOI for digital ones, tags are extremely instrumental in allowing others to critique an author’s work, thus explaining the commonality of tags in the not just the field of economics, but all academic writings. Like mentioned before, their audience being mostly other academics in the field of economics gives authors the flexibility of assuming knowledge in their readers. This explains why it’s not uncommon for authors to reference and use equations and models not present in the writing or that are only very briefly explained that are meant to be known by their audience: “This Kaleckian equation is analogous to the Keynesian equation of: W + Profits (broad) = Y = C + I”. Reuten goes into very little explanation of the Kaleckian and Keynesian equations and the variables in them and goes straight into manipulating them to provide as an explanation for an “increasing gap between profits and investments”. While collaboration and dialogue between the author and the audience is not unique to the field of economics, it is common and extremely vital to the furtherance of the field. The use and analysis of evidence and data to support claims is absolutely instrumental in any successful article in the economic field. When graphs are used in articles, they are referenced by their figure number and or their title to differentiate from other data sets in the writing. Any equation that is used is tagged with an identifying number in parentheses that is used to reference at later points in the piece with ease: “Rearranging equations (1) and (2) gives: R = I + C - (W + net interest paid by companies) (3)”. Contrary to the common practice of leaving out explanation and assuming the responsibility of knowledge onto the audience, when it comes to utilizing data, Economists are very careful in explaining the purpose of the data. Authors do this to make sure the audience understands exactly what they want them to get from the data presented and so the purpose of the evidence is not misconstrued. For example, Bussière et al. reference another one of

Gutierrez 3 their own articles and specifically say they “consider the importance of the contraction in trade as an international transmission channel” and reference a graph that shows a contraction of international trade in 2008 just to relay to the reader a link between international trade and the authors claim that world GDP growth rate has fallen. The article and the graph Bussière et al. reference present more data than they acknowledged for the purpose of making sure the reader only gets from the evidence what is relevant to the claim. Academic articles and entries in the field of economics are incredibly brief, dense, and to the point, making it difficult for those outside of the field to understand in full. However, this is acceptable considering the genre economists are writing in and to whom they are writing to. To be effective at writing in the field, economists are careful in choosing data and explaining their evidence to properly support their claims. They, for the most part, follow a uniform format so that articles can be easily navigated and can be referenced to allow for further conversation and the advancement of understanding in the field. Considering their audience, authors are able to use terminology and reference equations and models commonly used in economics without needing an explanation. Such conventions are observed in economic writings as they are conventions that allow for the most efficient furtherance of the knowledge and collaboration on the dismal science.

Gutierrez 4

Works Cited Bussière,

Matthieu,

et

al.

“The

Financial

Crisis:

Lessons

for

International

Macroeconomics.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, vol. 5, no. 3, 2013, pp. 75–84. JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/43189552. “Hedge Funds and the Financial Crisis of 2007–2008.” Hedge Funds and Systemic Risk, by Lloyd Dixon et al., RAND Corporation, Santa Monica, CA; Arlington, VA; Pittsburgh, PA, 2012, pp. 39–62. JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/10.7249/j.ctt1q60xr.12. Reuten, Geert. “Economic Stagnation Postponed: Background of the 2008 Financial-Economic Crisis in the European Union and the United States.” International Journal of Political Economy, vol. 40, no. 3, 2011, pp. 50–58., www.jstor.org/stable/23104261.

Related Documents

Wp2 Revised
June 2020 3
Wp2 Revised
July 2020 6
Wp2
October 2019 15
Wp2
October 2019 14
Wp2 Edited
July 2020 6
Pfl Wp2
June 2020 10