Infrastructure Investment And Economic Growth

  • November 2019
  • PDF

This document was uploaded by user and they confirmed that they have the permission to share it. If you are author or own the copyright of this book, please report to us by using this DMCA report form. Report DMCA


Overview

Download & View Infrastructure Investment And Economic Growth as PDF for free.

More details

  • Words: 4,711
  • Pages: 11
Policy Watch: Infrastructure Investment and Economic Growth Author(s): Alicia H. Munnell Source: The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 6, No. 4, (Autumn, 1992), pp. 189-198 Published by: American Economic Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2138275 Accessed: 06/04/2008 22:43 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://mc1www95.jstor.org:6085/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=aea. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit organization founded in 1995 to build trusted digital archives for scholarship. We enable the scholarly community to preserve their work and the materials they rely upon, and to build a common research platform that promotes the discovery and use of these resources. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

http://mc1www95.jstor.org:6085

Journal of EconomicPerspectives- Volume6, Number4-Fall 1992-Pages 189-198

Policy Watch Infrastructure Investment and Economic Growth Alicia H. Munnell

P

ublic policies are often made without much reliance on economic

reasoning. Economists are often unaware of what is happening in the world of public affairs. As a result, both the quality of public decisionmaking and the role that economists play in it are less than optimal. This feature contains short articles on topics that are currently on the agendas of policymakers, thus illustrating the role of economic analysis in current debates. Suggestions for future columns and comments on past ones should be sent to Isabel V. Sawhill, c/o Journal of Economic Perspectives, The Urban Institute, 2100 M Street N.W., Washington, D.C. 20037.

Introduction The stock of public capital in the United States is very large, $2.7 trillion in 1991 or about one-half the size of the private capital stock, according to data from the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis.' About $2.2 trillion of that IThe capital stock figures are calculated from historical investment figures revalued to current cost that are then cumulated and depreciated using a perpetual inventory method.

*Alicia H. Munnell is Senior VicePresidentand Directorof Research,Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Boston, Massachusetts.

190

Journal of Economic Perspectives

Table I Nonmilitary Nonresidential Net Public Capital Stock by Type of Asset, 1991 Public Capital Stock

Highwaysand Streets Waterand Sewer Systems Buildingsand Other Structures Schools, Hospitals,and Other Buildings Conservationand DevelopmentStructures Electricand Gas Facilities,Transit Systems,Airfields,etc. Equipment Total

Billions of Dollars

Percent of Total

$722.0 306.3

32 14

665.4 177.6

30 8

163.6 209.7 $2,250.5

7 9 100

Source:U.S. Bureau of EconomicAnalysis,unpublisheddata.

public capital stock is nonmilitary, with $1.9 billion held by state and local governments. Table 1 presents a breakdown. Despite its magnitude, public capital had been virtually ignored by the economics profession until the late 1980s. At that time, David Aschauer (1989) triggered a long overdue dialogue among economists and political leaders when he published a study arguing that much of the decline in U.S. productivity that occurred in the 1970s was precipitated by declining rates of public capital investment. My own work confirmed these results (Munnell, 1990a). Spending advocates seized on these findings as support for increased public investment. Transportation Secretary Samuel Skinner and New Jersey Governor James Florio joined traditional interest groups to argue that more public investment in infrastructure would help the economy. Prominent economists signed a national petition for increased infrastructure spending. Several congressional committees held hearings on this topic. The U.S. Council of Mayors (1992) called for stimulative infrastructure spending earlier this year, and Governor Clinton has made infrastructure spending a major part of his economic plan. Felix Rohatyn (1992) argued for very large increases in infrastructure investment in a recent article in New YorkReview of Books. The enthusiasm among policymakers for the early Aschauer results was matched, if not surpassed, by skepticism on the part of many economists. Critics of these studies charged that the methodology was flawed, that the direction of causation between public investment and output growth is unclear and that, even if the historical empirical relationships were estimated correctly, they provide no clear indications for current policy. Who's right? What do we know and not know about the link between public infrastructure and productivity? And what are the implications of these results for policy?

Alicia H. Munnell

191

Public Capital and the Production Process Everyone agrees that public capital investment can expand the productive capacity of an area, both by increasing resources and by enhancing the productivity of existing resources. A well-constructed highway allows a truck driver to avoid circuitous back roads and to transport goods to market in less time. The reduction in required time means that the producer pays the driver lower wages and the truck experiences less wear and tear. Hence, public investment in a highway enables private companies to produce their products at lower total cost. The condition of the highway, of course, is just as important as its existence. Similar stories can be told for mass transit, water and sewer systems, and other components of public capital. Beginning with Aschauer's work, a number of studies have estimated regressions where the dependent variable is output within some area, and the independent variables are private capital, labor, public capital, and a constant for the level of technology.2 In such regressions, the levels of public capital are generally significant, and the consensus is that Aschauer made a significant contribution by drawing attention to the importance of public infrastructure and by adding public capital to the conventional production function. The controversy arises about the method of estimating this expanded function and about the interpretation of the results. Aschauer's original aggregate time series estimates (1989), my reestimates (1990a), and earlier work by Holz-Eakin (1988) suggest that the impact of aggregate public capital on private sector output and productivity is very large. My own equations indicate that a 1 percent increase in the stock of public capital would increase output by .34 percent. Given the size of the public capital stock and output, these figures imply a marginal productivity of public capital of roughly 60 percent; that is, a $1 increase in the public capital stock would raise output by $.60. The marginal productivity of private capital estimated from these equations is about 30 percent. Looking at similar numbers, Aschauer (1990, p. 16) concludes that "increases in GNP resulting from increased public infrastructure spending are estimated to exceed those from private investment by a factor of between two and five." In my view, the implied impact of public infrastructure investment on private sector output emerging from the aggregate time series studies is too large to be credible. It does not make sense for public capital investment to

public capital as an input whose services enhance the productivity of both capital and labor yields the equation Q = (MFP)*f(K, L, G), where Q is output, MFP is the level of technology, K is the private capital stock, L is labor, and G is the stock of public capital. Assuming a generalized Cobb-Douglas form of technology yields a more specific relationship between inputs and outputs: Q = MFP*KaLbGC. Translating this equation into logarithms produces a linear function that can be estimated: ln Q = ln MFP + a ln K + b ln L + c ln G. The coefficients a, b, and c are the output elasticities of factor inputs. In other words, the coefficients indicate the percentage change in output for a given percentage change in factor input.

2Treating

192

Journal of EconomicPerspectives

have a substantially greater impact on private sector output than private capital investment, particularly considering that so much public investment goes for improving the environment and other goals that are not captured in national output measures. To obtain more evidence, I looked at the relationship between public capital and measures of economic activity at the state level (Munnell, 1990b). Since no data on state-level public or private capital stocks were available, the first step was to construct stock estimates; these estimates were then used in three separate exercises. The first, parallel to the national work, estimated production functions for states and found that public capital had a significant, positive impact on output, although the output elasticity was roughly one-half the size of the national estimate. The second analysis examined the relationship between public and private investment, which is characterized by two opposing forces. On one hand, public capital enhances the productivity of private capital, raising its rate of return and encouraging more investment. On the other hand, from the investor's perspective, public capital acts as a substitute for private capital and "crowds out" private investment. The estimated equations confirmed both forces but suggested that, on balance, public capital investment stimulates private investment. The third exercise used a business location model to explore the relationship between public capital and employment growth. Here the average annual change in employment was estimated as a function of variables reflecting input costs (labor, energy, land), market size, tax burden, and public capital stock. The results showed that, after accounting for all the other factors that affect employment, public capital had a positive, statistically significant effect on employment growth.3 Taken together, these three analyses indicate that public capital has a positive impact on several measures of state-level economic activity: output, investment, and employment growth. The magnitudes of these effects are considerably smaller than those found at the national level; for instance, the elasticity of public capital with respect to output was .15, roughly half the estimate at the national level. These estimates are consistent with the estimates of other researchers working at the state level (Mera, 1973; Costa, Ellson, and Martin, 1987; Garcia-Mila and McGuire, 1992).

Enter the Critics Critics have leveled three major changes at the results emerging from estimated production functions. First, they contend that common trends in the output and public infrastructure data have led to a spurious correlation. Second, they argue that the wide range of estimates emerging from the various 3This estimated effect on state employment may overestimate the national impact if employment is merely diverted from one area to another.

Policy Watch 193

studies renders the coefficients suspect. Finally, they suggest that causation runs not from public capital to output, but rather in the other direction. The most vociferous critics, concerned about the seemingly clarion call for dramatically increased public investment, focus mainly on the aggregate time series; they argue essentially that the equations should be estimated in the form of first differences (Aaron, 1990; Hulten and Schwab, 1991; Jorgenson, 1991; Tatom, 1991). Specifically, they contend that the data are not stationary but tend to drift over time, and that it is necessary to remove this trend to eliminate spurious correlations and determine the true relationship between the two variables. This means specifying the relationship in terms of first differences, which often yields results showing that public capital's effect is quite small, sometimes negative, and generally not statistically significant. The first-differencing specification has its problems, however. After all, no one would expect the growth in the capital stock, whether private or public, in one year to be correlated with the growth in output in that same year. In fact, equations estimated in this form often yield implausible coefficients for labor and private capital as well as for public capital (Evans and Karras, 1991; Hulten and Schwab, 1991; Tatom, 1991). However, researchers do not conclude from these misspecified equations that private capital and labor do not contribute to private sector output. In addition, first-differencing destroys any long-term relationship in the data, which is exactly what one is trying to estimate. Instead of just first-differencing, the variables should be tested for co-integration, adjusted, and estimated accordingly. That is, researchers should examine not just whether the variables grow over time, that is, the extent to which they are nonstationary, but also whether they grow together over time and converge to their long-run relationship, that is, the extent to which they are co-integrated.4 The second broad criticism is that the wide range of estimates of public capital's impact on output makes the empirical linkages fragile at best. In my view, the critics are seriously misreading the evidence. In almost all cases the impact of public capital on private sector output and productivity has been positive and statistically significant. This finding is amazing, given that much public capital spending is designed to alleviate environmental problems or enhance the quality of life, and therefore contributes little to national output as conventionally measured. Furthermore, the coefficients at each level of government tend to be very similar across studies, as shown in Table 2. The variation between estimates occurs as the unit of observation moves from the nation to states to cities. As the geographic focus narrows, the estimated impact of public capital becomes smaller. The most obvious explanation is that, because of leakages, one cannot ratom (1991) adjusts for co-integration by including in the equation all significant leads and lags of the independent variables and finds public capital's effect to be negative and insignificant. However, Tatom's effort has been criticized for including the price of energy in an equation with the quantities of other factor inputs. Clearly, more work is needed, and it should focus on adjusting for co-integration rather than mechanically first-differencing all variables.

4

194

Journal of Economic Perspectives

Table 2

Production Function Estimates of the Output Elasticity of Public Capital by Level of Geographic Aggregation

Author

Aschauer (1989) Holz-Eakin (1988) Munnell (1990a) Costa, Ellson, Martin (1987) Eisner (1991) Mera (1973) Munnell (1990b) Duffy-Deno and Eberts (1989)a Eberts (1986, 1990)

Specification

Output Elasticityof Public Capital

National National National

Cobb-Douglas; Log levels Cobb-Douglas; Log levels Cobb-Douglas; Log levels

.39 .39 .34

States States Japanese regions States

Translog; Levels Cobb-Douglas; Log levels Cobb-Douglas; Log levels Cobb-Douglas; Log levels

.20 .17 .20 .15

Metropolitan areas Metropolitan areas

Log levels Translog; Levels

.08 .03

Level of Aggregation

Note: Results from the first-difference model used by Aaron (1990), Hulten and Schwab (1991), and other critics are not included because they yielded implausible coefficients on the private inputs. aThe authors do not estimate a production function, but instead use personal income as the dependent variable.

capture all of the payoff to an infrastructure investment by looking at a small geographic area. The third major criticism is that the direction of causation may run from high levels of output to greater public capital investment, rather than the other way around. The criticism is legitimate. Capital investment, private as well as public, goes hand in hand with economic activity. However, this mutual influence can exist without necessarily tainting the coefficient on public capital, or, for that matter, private capital in estimated production functions. Eberts and Fogarty (1987) examined the question of causality by looking at public and private investment data from 1904 to 1978 for 40 metropolitan areas. They found causation running in both directions. Their analysis indicated that public investment led private investment in cities that experienced most of their growth before the 1950s, while the reverse was true for southern cities and cities that grew faster since 1950. To examine the simultaneity issue, I reestimated some equations using the state data, but included only the value of public capital at the beginning of the period, which foreclosed the possibility of any feedback effect of output growth on public capital investment. Nonetheless, public capital continued to exhibit a large, positive, statistically significant effect on output. This small exercise does not put the question to rest, but does suggest that the coefficient of public capital is not seriously tainted by the simultaneity problem. Other critics have suggested that the production function framework is inadequate, both because it omits input prices (which affect factor utilization

Alicia H. Munnell

195

and bias the estimated coefficients) and also because it places too many restrictions on firms' technology and behavior (Friedlaender, 1990; Morrison and Schwartz, 1992). They believe that researchers should instead estimate cost functions, which allow one to disentangle the effects of infrastructure, scale economies, and fixed effects on costs and the cost-output relationship. Dalenberg and Eberts (1992), Morrison and Schwartz (1992), and Nadiri and Mamuneas (1992) all adopt the cost-function approach and find that public capital significantly reduces the costs of private production. In summary, the critics are correct that the numbers emerging from the aggregate time series studies are not credible, and that more evidence is needed on the causation issue. But the tendency to throw the baby out with the bathwater should be resisted. At this point, an even-handed reading of the the growing body of cross-sectional results-suggests that evidence-including public infrastructure is a productive input which may have large payoffs.

Does the Nation Need More Public Investment? If infrastructure has substantial payoffs, does this imply that public capital is undersupplied and higher levels of investment are warranted? At this time, production function estimates provide little guidance on this point, but some other evidence seems to support the notion that profitable public investment opportunities exist. For example, cost-benefit studies reported by the Congressional Budget Office (1988) indicate that the return to projects designed to maintain the average condition on the federal highway system could be as high as 30 to 40 percent. The CBO (1991) also suggests the likelihood of substantial benefits from increased outlays for both air traffic control and airport capacity expansions.

Another piece of evidence comes from the work of George Peterson (1990, 1991). He explored voters' preferences for public capital investment as expressed in bond elections and other referenda. If public officials were trying to satisfy the median voter, as theory suggests, they would submit frequent bond proposals for consideration to assess voter demand. As a result, bond elections should be closely contested with bond approval rates and margins close to 50 percent. Instead, Peterson found that 80 percent of infrastructure bond proposals were approved between 1984 and 1989, and that the margin exceeded 66 percent on average.5 Although only 25 percent of capital spending passes through the referendum process, this experience suggests that voters are willing to pay for more infrastructure spending. 5Aaron (1991) offers a note of caution concerning Peterson's work. Specifically, he points out that elected officials control the supply of proposals and it is very difficult to make any determinations about voters' demands for infrastructure without analyzing changes in supply. Aaron concludes, however, that he would not be surprised if Peterson's claims are entirely correct, but does not feel that the case has been proven yet.

196

Journal of EconomicPerspectives

Despite such findings, several voices urge caution when considering increased spending for public infrastructure. For example, Clifford Winston and his colleagues contend that the condition of the nation's highways could be improved and congestion reduced with the same or less investment by making three changes (Winston, 1990, 1991; Small, Winston, and Evans, 1989). First, building roads thicker than prevailing engineering standards would produce great savings. Second, shifting from a tax on the number of truck axles to one on weight per axle would greatly encourage efficient use of highways and minimize damage. Third, increasing the use of congestion taxes would reduce peak-period congestion and increase the services provided by existing capacity. Others point to inefficiencies in our federal grant programs, where matching rates are probably much higher than can be justified on the basis of interjurisdictional spillovers (Gramlich, 1990, 1991). As a result, many states pay as little as 10 cents on the dollar for new highways, giving little reason to believe that they will make economically sensible decisions about infrastructure investment. Those who worry about the incentives to spend, the efficiency of design, and the appropriateness of the prices charged tend -to believe that infrastructure policy should focus on eliminating current distortions and inefficiencies. They seem to believe that once the perversities in the existing system are removed, the present stock of infrastructure can meet most of the nation's needs. Additional investment at this time will divert attention and alleviate the pressure to make needed pricing reforms. Although these concerns about pricing and grant programs should be addressed, my hunch is that these reforms will be slow in coming and the country will still need more spending to repair roads and bridges, treat wastewater, dispose of trash, and improve the quality of the nation's lakes and rivers.

Conclusion Some proponents of expanded infrastructure investment are truly interested in the effect that additional spending will have on economic activity; others are at least as interested in the potential or lucrative contracts coming their way. The immediacy of policy implications places great demands on economists, both not to oversell preliminary results and not to dismiss a growing body of evidence. It has proved a difficult environment in which to make a calm assessment of the evidence. That said, my views are as follows. This is an area ripe for research that could have important policy implications. Researchers should focus on explaining the variations in the coefficients by level of government, disentangling the causation question, and examining the cointegration issue. Aggregate results, however, cannot be used to guide actual investment spending. Only cost-benefit studies can determine which projects should be implemented. Finally, while reforms to grant programs and pricing should occur, it is probably neither realistic nor desirable to hold off on infrastructure investment until such

Policy Watch 197

reforms are adopted. For the evidence suggests that, in addition to providing immediate economic stimulus, public infrastructure investment has a significant, positive effect on output and growth.

References Aaron, Henry J., "Discussion of 'Why Is Infrastructure Important?'" In Munnell, Alicia H., ed., Is There a Shortfall in Public Capital Investment? Conference Series No. 34, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, June 1990, 51-63. Aaron, Henry J., "Discussion of 'Historical Perspectives on Infrastructure Investment: How Did We Get Where We Are?'" Paper presented by George E. Peterson at the American Enterprise Institute Conference on "Infrastructure Needs and Policy Options for the 1990s," Washington, D.C, February 4, 1991. Aschauer, David Alan, "Is Public Expenditure Productive?" Journal of Monetary Economics, March 1989, 23, 177-200. Aschauer, David Alan, "Does Public Capital Crowd Out Private Capital?" Journal of Monetary Economics,September 1989, 24, 171-88. Aschauer, David Alan, Public Investmentand Private Sector Growth. Washington, D.C.: Economic Policy Institute, 1990. Congressional Budget Office, New Directionsfor the Nation's Public Works.Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, September 1988. Congressional Budget Office, How Federal Spending for Infrastructureand Other Public InvestmentsAffectsthe Economy.Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, July 1991. Costa, Jose da Silva, Richard W. Ellson, and Randolph C. Martin, "Public Capital, Regional Output, and Development: Some Empirical Evidence," Journal of Regional Science, August 1987, 27, 419-37. Dalenberg, Douglas R. and Randall W. Eberts, "Estimates of the Manufacturing Sector's Desired Level of Public Capital: A Cost Function Approach," Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Western Economic Association, San Francisco, California, July 10-13, 1992. Duffy-Deno, Kevin T., and Randall W. Eberts, "Public Infrastructure and Regional Economic Development: A Simultaneous Approach," Working Paper No. 8909, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, August 1989.

Eberts, Randall W., "Estimating the Contribution of Urban Public Infrastructure to Regional Economic Growth," Working Paper No. 8610, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, December 1986. Eberts, Randall W., 'Public Infrastructure and Regional Economic Development," Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Quarter 1, 1990, 26, 15-27. Eberts, Randall W. and Michael S. Fogarty, "Estimating the Relationship Between Local Public and Private Investment," Working Paper No. 8703, Fedral Reserve Bank of Cleveland, May 1987. Eisner, Robert, "Infrastructure and Regional Economic Performance," New England Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, September/October 1991, 47-58. Evans, Paul and Georgios Karras, "Are Government Activities Productive? Evidence from a Panel of U.S. States," unpublished, Ohio State University, October 1991. Friedlaender, Ann F., "Discussion of'How Does Public Infrastructure Affect Regional Economic Performance?"' In Munnell, Alicia H., ed., Is There a Shortfall in Public Capital Investment?Conference Series No. 34, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 1990, 108-12. Garcia-Mila, Theresa and Therese J. McGuire, "The Contribution of Publicly Provided Inputs to States' Economies," Regional Scienceand UrbanEconomics,forthcoming 1992. Gramlich, Edward M., "How Should Public Infrastructure Be Financed?" In Munnell, Alicia H., ed., Is Therea Shortfall in Public Capital Investment?Conference Series No. 34, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, June 1990, 223-37. Gramlich, Edward M., "U.S. Infrastructure Needs: Let's Get the Prices Right." Paper presented at the American Enterprise Institute Conference on "Infrastructure Needs and Policy Options for the 1990s," Washington, D.C, February 4, 1991. Holz-Eakin, Douglas, "Private Output, Government Capital, and the Infrastructure 'Crisis'" Discussion Paper Series No. 394, New York: Columbia University, May 1988.

198

Journal of EconomicPerspectives

Hulten, Charles, R. and Robert M. Schwab, "Is There Too Little Public Capital? Infrastructure and Economic Growth." Paper presented at the American Enterprise Institute Conference on "Infrastructure Needs and Policy Options for the 1990s," Washington, D.C., February 4, 1991. Jorgenson, Dale W., "Fragile Statistical Foundations: The Macroeconomics of Public Infrastructure Investment." Paper presented at the American Enterprise Institute Conference on "Infrastructure Needs and Policy Options for the 1990s," Washington, D.C., February 4, 1991. Mera, Koichi, "Regional Production Functions and Social Overhead Capital: An Analysis of the Japanese Case," Regional and Urban Economics,May 1973, 3, 157-85. Morrison, Catherine J. and Amy E. Schwartz, "State Infrastructure and Productive Performance," Working Paper No. 3981, Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research, January 1992. Munnell, Alicia H., "Why Has Productivity Declined? Productivity and Public Investment," New England Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, January/ February 1990a, 3-22. Munnell, Alicia H., with the assistance of Leah M. Cook, "How Does Public Infrastructure Affect Regional Economic Performance?," New England EconomicReview, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, September/October 1990b, 11-32. Nadiri, M. Ishaq and Theofanis P. Mamuneas, "The Effects of Public Infrastructure and R&D Capital on the Cost Structure and Performance of U.S. Manufacturing Industries," mimeo, New York University, February 1992. National Council on Public Works Improvement, Fragile Foundations: A Report on America'sPublic Works.Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, February 1988. Peterson, George E., "Is Public Infrastructure Undersupplied?" In Munnell, Alicia H., ed., Is There a Shortfall in Public Capital Investment? Conference Series No. 34, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, June 1990, 113-35. Peterson, George E., "Historical Perspectives on Infrastructure Investment: How Did We Get Where We Are?" Paper presented at the American Enterprise Institute Conference on "Infrastructure Needs and Policy Option for the 1990s," Washington, D.C., February 4, 1991. Rohatyn, Felix, "What the Government Should Do," New YorkReview of Books, June

25, 1992. Small, Kenneth A., Clifford Winston, and Carol A. Evans, Road Work: A New Highway Pricing and InvestmentPolicy. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1989. Tatom, John A., "Public Capital and Private Sector Performance," Review, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, May/June 1991, 73, 3-15. U.S. Conference of Mayors, Ready to Go: A Survey of USA Public WorksProjects to Fight the RecessionNow. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Conference of Mayors, 1992. U.S. Congress, Office of Technology Assessment, Rebuilding the Foundations: State and Local Public WorksFinancing and Management. Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, March 1990. U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Government Finances: 1988-89. Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, February 1991. U.S. Department of Transportation, Moving America: New Directions, New Opportunities. Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, February 1990. U.S. House of Representatives, Committee on the Budget, Task Force on Community Development and Natural Resources, "Hearings on Investments in America's Hometowns: Community Development, Issues in Urban Areas and Other Places." Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, September 26, 1991. U.S. House of Representatives, Committee on Public Works and Transportation, "Hearings on Our Nation's Transportation and Core Infrastructure." Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, February 20, 1991. U.S. House of Representatives, "The Status of the Nation's Highways and Bridges: Conditions and Performance." Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, September 1991. U.S. Senate, Committee on Environment and Public Works, Subcommittee on Water Resources, Transportation, and Infrastructure, "Hearings on Infrastructure, Productivity, and Economic Growth." Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, February 5, 1991. Winston, Clifford M., "How Efficient Is Current Infrastructure Spending and Pricing?" In Munnell, Alicia H., ed., Is There a Shortfall in Public Capital Investment? Conference Series No. 34, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, June 1990, 183-205. Winston, Clifford M., "Efficient Transportation Infrastructure Policy," Journal of EconomicPerspectives,Winter 1991, 5, 113-27.

Related Documents