Esho Paper

  • Uploaded by: srinath
  • 0
  • 0
  • December 2019
  • PDF

This document was uploaded by user and they confirmed that they have the permission to share it. If you are author or own the copyright of this book, please report to us by using this DMCA report form. Report DMCA


Overview

Download & View Esho Paper as PDF for free.

More details

  • Words: 5,193
  • Pages: 15
Global Development Network Fifth Annual Global Development Conference New Delhi

Indian Development Strategy and Economic Performance Mirrored in the Eyes of a Japanese Hideki Esho

1. History Matters: Looking Back the Development History of Independent India 1-1 At the Beginning During the Nehru era, people thought that India was the most promising developing country among the newly independent countries. India was democratic, its economic size was huge, and the intellectual level of its professionals, such as high-level bureaucrats, lawyers, professors, and journalists, was high. Not only that, but there were entrepreneur groups who had developed indigenous technologies since the late 19th century. Such things attracted the minds of Westerners and produced a great expectation among them for the future of India1. Soon after the Partition, Indian government introduced an economic development strategy of five-year plans. During the Second Five-Year Plan, which started in 1955, a heavy industry priority plan was adopted based on the famous Mahalanobis's two-sector growth model2. Then, in 1956, the Industrial Policy Resolution was promulgated by which key industries such as heavy and chemical industries were entrusted to public sector units. Also, by this Resolution, licensing systems were

1

Rostow's argument was a typical one (W. W. Rostow, Stages of Economic Growth: A

Non-Communist Manifest, London: Cambridge University Press, 1960). I slightly remember my childhood in India. Jawahalral Nehru presented us an elephant named Indira when the Japanese economy was still in the doldrums soon after the end of the Second World War. It was a silver lining for us. Nehru was definitely one of the most popular political leaders for Japanese at that time. Even today I have a sweet memory of the gentleness of the Indian people. 2

Mahalanobis was a star in the age of high expectations for economic development. Sir Hans Singer

tells us that "P. C. Mahalanobis became the prophet (or guru) of the development economics in this [development planning] respect, and Calcutta became their Mecca". (H. W. Sineger, "The Terms of Trade Controversy and the Evolution of Soft Financing: Early Years in the U.N." in Gearld M. Meier and Dudly Seers eds., Pioneers in Development, Published for the World Bank: Oxford University Press, 1984. See also Ashok Rudra, Prasanta Chandra Mahalanobis: A Biography, Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1996.)

1

introduced to regulate private sector companies. A mixed economy system, under which the share of public sector was predominant, was formulated in such a manner.

1-2 The First Turning Point Indian society faced its first turning point in the mid-sixties. Prime Minister Nehru died in 1964 and India lost an outstanding leader. The monsoon rainfalls were meager in the successive years of 1964 and 1965 so that agricultural production was heavily damaged and India was obliged to import food grain. On top of this, border conflicts occurred between India and China in 1962, and between India and Pakistan in 1965. A large amount of the national budget was subsequently allocated to defense purposes and the fiscal deficit was swelled. Under the tri-lemma of a food crisis, fiscal crisis, and rising inflationary pressures, India faced a serious foreign exchange shortage. The Indian government approached the World Bank to overcome this crisis. The World Bank promised to provide assistance to India on the condition that the Indian government would adopt a package of deregulation measures, including a substantial devaluation of the rupee. Following this recommendation, the Indian government devalued the rupee in June 1966. Under the pressure of the Cold War between the U.S. and Soviet Russia, the U.S. government cut financial assistance to India on the ground that the India-Pakistan war not yet ended. As well, the promised assistance from the World Bank to India failed to materialize. This "betrayal" by the U.S. government and the World Bank has affected decisively the course of Indian political and economic management since then3.

1-3 Toward a Closed Economy Gaining political power after the Fourth General Election of 1967, Prime Minister Indira Gandhi initiated a campaign against the U.S.. Thinking it was a necessity for India to establish food self-sufficiency as part of an independent national economy, Indira Gandhi intently introduced a green revolution strategy in the Fourth Five-Year Plan. With this, India could attain food self-sufficiency by 1977. Indira Gandhi also propagated "Garibi Hatao” (eradication of poverty) to obtain the support of the poor and left wing political parties. As a measure, 14 major commercial banks were nationalized. During Indira Gandhi era, the style of Indian economic management changed drastically, with the decision making power of the Planning Commission becoming substantially diluted. The prime

3

Francine R. Frankel, India's Political Economy, 1947-1977: The Gradual Revolution, Princeton:

Princeton University Press, 1978, Chapters 7-8. See also a classical analysis by Bhagwati and Srinivasan on this first liberalization episode (Jagdish Bhagwati and T. N. Srinivasan, Foreign Trade Regimes and Economic Development: India, New York and London: Columbia University Press, 1975.

2

minister concentrated power, and ad-hoc political intervention to economic management increased. Beginning in the mid-1960s, the Indian economy began to suffer a long period of stagnation, and it was said that the economy could not exceed growth of 3.5 percent per annum. This was called the barrier of the "Hindu growth rate". The main reason for this long-term stagnation was macro-economic management under India’s closed economy, and during this era, the FERA regulations were strengthened and the MRTP Act was introduced. American capital such as IBM and the Coca-Cola left India. Japanese investors also almost pulled their interests from India, and what Professor Bhagwati called "a rentier society" or "directly unproductive, profit-seeking activities" were embedded4. In 1974, the annual inflation rate exceeded 20 percent, hit by the first oil crisis and an insufficient monsoon. In India, when the inflation rate exceeded 10 percent, political unrest was often fostered and followed by a change in government. In 1974 too, an anti-Indira Gandhi government movement arose. The Prime Minister declared a state of emergency and a dictatorial regime appeared for the first time in the contemporary Indian history. Against this regime, J. P. Narayan organized a mass movement against Indira Gandhi that ended with her imprisonment. Under a slogan of the revival of democracy, the Janata Party formed a new government. However, under the Janata government, the economy was not able to recover, and with the second oil crisis of 1979, India again faced serious inflationary pressures, a foreign exchange crisis, and a food crisis. The Janata government experienced a miserable collapse and in the general election of 1981, Indira Ghandi miraculously regained power.

1-4 Transformation Period Soon after returning to power, Indira Gandhi asked the IMF to assist India in overcoming its BOP crisis, and she subsequently managed to obtain the huge sum of 5 billion SDRs. Quite naturally, the IMF exerted conditionality on the Indian government and a fierce protest against this decision quickly spread across the country. An abominable memory of 1966 became revived in the minds of the people. Prime Minister Indira Gandhi, however, dispelled these objections and was able to promote a certain degree of deregulation. Taking a chance, Suzuki Motor Company of Japan entered the Indian market, forming a joint venture company with Maruti. Maruti became a symbol of the New India, although the economic liberalization of India was still in a nascent period. In the 1970s, the world changed from a system dominated by engineering technology to electronics technology. Japan was a pioneer of this technological innovation, and East and

4

Jagdish Bhagwati and Padma Desai, "Socialism and Indian Economic Policy," World Development,

Vol.13 No. 4, 1975; Jadgish Bhagwati, "Directly Unproductive, Profit-Seeking (DUP) Activities," Journal of Political Economy, Vol.50 No.5, 1982.

3

South-East Asian countries also enjoyed the fruits of this technological innovation by actively accepting FDI. India, however, failed to embrace the new technology. India stuck to the old engineering technology under the closed economy system. When Indian leader Indira Gandhi was assassinated in 1984, her first son Rajib Gandhi became Prime Minister, further promoting deregulation and opening up of the country. He believed that modernizing the electronics industry was key to the development of society and as such, launched a modernization program for goods like consumer electronics and software. Despite these changes, though, throughout the 1980s, India’s liberalization measures did not change the fundamental regulation system that had dominated the Indian economy since the Nehru era.

2. After the Crisis of 1991: Advent of the New Era 2-1 The Second Turning Point In 1991, India was again hit by a very serious political and economic crisis comparable to that of 1966. Foreign exchange reserves decreased to a level sufficient for only two weeks of imports and India faced a debt crisis. The Narasimha Rao government took power in the Tenth General Election, and the new Prime Minister appointed Dr. Manmohan Singh as finance minister. Dr. Singh launched a bold economic liberalization program (New Economic Policy) that depended on financial assistance from the IMF and World Bank. Guided by these institution’s structural adjustment programs, India’s NEP also consisted of stabilization with deregulation, liberalization, privatization, and globalization, following the neo-classical development economics (or Washington Consensus) belief that the market works well, even in developing countries. Deserving special attention is that in the case of India, its NEP did not proceeded at the same speed, sequence, or extent as those of structural adjustment programs advocated by the IMF and the World Bank. Hence, the key lessons that we can learn from the Indian NEP experience are that those programs were done under strong Indian ownership, and the government's commitment to the NEP was clear, so that India could gain high credibility from international society. Dr. Manmohan Singh, especially managed extremely well the two-year first phase of the structural adjustment program called stabilization aimed at the control of inflation by cutting budgetary deficits, controlling the money supply, and devaluing the rupee. Because of India’s splendid success in stabilization management, India got a high reputation from the international society. People who bitterly criticized the liberalization policy in 1981 kept silent in 1991, as the economic crisis of 1991 was so severe and the collapse of Soviet bloc hugely influenced Indian political and economic management. Dr. Singh’s deregulated industrial licensing policy substantially liberalized FDI and trade policy. The NEP era had begun5.

5

There are quite a large numbers of evaluations on Indian NEP, the most notable of which are: Amit

4

2-2 Economic Performance after the NEP: Some Emerging New Trends Since the NEP era began, we have seen an unusual combination of an "unstable political situation" and "remarkable economic recovery and growth". While the economy has smoothly revived, general elections were held four times in an eight-year period since 1991. There have been some notable features of economic performances since the introduction of the NEP, giving evidence that the Indian economy has entered a new phase.

(1) Secular and Rising Economic Growth Table 1 indicates that not only annual average economic growth rates between 1992-93 and 1999-2000 exceeded 6 percent but that the extent of fluctuation narrowed. The real GDP growth rates from 1992-93 to 1996-97 was 5.1 percent, 5.9 percent, 7.2 percent, 7.5 percent, and 8.2 percent, respectively. This is really a secular and rising trend. One of the reasons why such a secular growth trajectory was realized was that economic growth became less affected by the fluctuations of agricultural production. In the long run, we can say that the Indian economy reached the stage where a 6 percent annual economic growth rate was attainable. The magnitude of such a growth rate is outstanding compared to those of African or Latin American developing countries, and needless to say is much higher than for industrialized countries.

(2) Improvement of Macro-economic Balance Gross domestic savings as a percent of GDP substantially increased after the introduction of the NEP. It peaked at 25.1 percent in 1995-96, its historically highest ratio. As a result, the savings-investment gap (gross domestic savings minus gross domestic capital formation) narrowed to 0.3-1.7 percent per GDP since 1993-94. The gaps were about 3 to 4 percent in the latter half of the 1980s (see Table 2). In addition, the financing ability of investment by domestic savings increased. This is really a favorable effect for the NEP.

(3) Private-Sector-led Investment Table 3 shows the composition of gross domestic savings and gross domestic capital formation by

Bhaduri and Deepak Nayyar, Intelligent Person's Guide to Liberalization, Penguin Books, 1996; Isher Judge Ahluwalia and I. M. D. Little eds., India's Economic Reforms and Development: Essays for Manmohan Singh, Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1998; Jeffrey D. Sachs, Ashutosh Varshney, and Nirupam Bajpai eds., India in the Era of Economic Reforms, Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1999; Jean Dreze and Amartya Sen eds., India: Development and Participation, Oxford: Clarendon Press, 2002. Shankar Acharya, "Macroeconomic Management in the Nineties," Economic and Political Weekly, April 20,2002.

5

economic agents. On the savings side, although the household sector has been a major saver as usual, the conspicuous phenomenon is that the savings rate of the private corporate sector increased since the inception of the NEP. It increased up to 5.0 percent in 1995-96. On the contrary, that of the public sector remained stagnant and even worsened during the same period. It shows that the public sector reform has not progressed at all. On the investment side too, we can see a remarkable change before and after the NEP. After the NEP period there is a clear trend that the share of private sector investment supersedes that of the public sector investment. During the 1980s, especially in the latter half of the 1980s, India enjoyed relatively high economic growth. That growth, however, was realized by depending on massive public sector investment, which in turn was only made possible by depending on domestic as well as foreign loans. As a result of this financing pattern, both the fiscal deficits and foreign debt accumulated. Hence, relatively high growth was attained only at the cost of the rising macro-economic imbalances, which led to the 1991 crisis. Economic recovery and growth under the NEP, however, is quite different from this pattern. This is really a notable change. Private sector investment is the driving force of high economic growth in the NEP period, another favorable new phenomenon made possible by economic liberalization.

(4) Changing Industrial Structure Because of the phenomenal growth of the service industry, the Indian industrial structure has been quickly changing. The main factors that made high growth under the NEP possible have been the substantial growth of service sector and revival of the manufacturing sector. During the 1990s, the service sector share of the total GDP increased by 7 per cent, and its share of the total GDP increased to 47.1 percent. Looking at the use-based classification of the industrial production outlined in Table 4, we also recognize that growth was predominated by the high growth of consumer durable goods. These developments of the service sector and consumer durable goods were driven by the vigorous demands of the so-called new middle class. Especially in the mega-cities such as Delhi, Mumbai, Chennai, Bangalore, Hyderabad and so on, the number of the new rich is quickly increasing and their lifestyles are also quickly changing. Notable changes, for example, are an increasing number of owned houses and flats, cars and consumer electronic goods (see Table 5). Definitely some Indians feel that their lives have improved dramatically. My first visit to India as a tourist was in 1974. At that time Delhi, even Bombay, were still calm cities. I was very much attracted by the Indian society, quite different from Japanese society at that time. Yet, these good old days of Indian style have passed away!

6

(5) Accumulation of Foreign Exchange Reserves The increase in exports under the period of the NEP was not unsatisfactory. Invisible trade also improved a lot, so that the current account deficits as per GDP decreased (see Table 6). One notable development was that foreign exchange reserves accumulated so dramatically (see Table 7), and this rising trend of foreign exchange continues to today. As of June 2003, the total surpassed US$83 billion.

(6) Increasing Inflow of Foreign Capital Foreign capital inflow has increased remarkably since 1993-94 (see Table 8). The total amount of foreign investment inflow increased to about US$6 billion in 2001-02, of which foreign direct investment (FDI) accounted for about US$4 billion, and portfolio investment (PI) was about US$2 billion. Especially since the Asian currency crisis of 1997, the Indian government has seemed to be trying to attract FDI more positively, and not PI. Although the amount of FDI jumped up if we compare the totals before and after the NEP, still the Indian figure are not so dramatic compared to other Asian countries, especially China (see Table 9).

(7) Emerging South India The catchword that best expresses the characteristics of the Indian economy after the NEP is consumption boom. Not only Delhi and Mumbai, the traditional consumption centers, but also the Southern Indian states joined this new trend. If we look at the changing trends of the rural consumption markets in 1990s, the share of North India declined from 16.4 percent to 12.2 percent, while the share of Southern India increased from 38.7 percent to 57.0 percent6. It has been said that the main reasons for this degree of consumption boom in the Southern India are as follows. Firstly, there is a well-developed credit culture, and based on this, a consumer credit system permeated society. Secondly, the new industries such as ICT, biotechnology, multimedia, real estate, healthcare, and financial services, are quickly developing. Thirdly, there are stable political environments and the governments undertaking economic reforms at the state level. The representative case is AP led by Chief Minister Mr. N. Chandrababu Naidu. Fourthly, the area has good quality workers. Fifthly, there are investment friendly environments in the area. Sixthly, social indicators such as education, health, and medical care are relatively better than in other Indian regions. And finally, the culture and history of this area are quite different from of the rest of India.

6

The Economic Times, January 28, 2001.

7

(8) ICT Industry -- A Flag-bearer of the New Economy The most important factor supporting the consumption boom of Southern India is the conspicuous development of the ICT industry located in major Southern Indian cities. As the ICT industry is a typical knowledge-intensive industry, its development changes the international image of the Indian people and society. These days, many of my Japanese friends who used to have no interest in India, know tell me that Indians are geniuses in mathematics and extremely good at English. They say that the Indian learning reaches an incredibly high level, citing that Indians can memorize 100 by 100 multiplication! The developmental core of the Indian ICT industry is software, which has been growing 50 percent every year since 1991 (see Table 10). Especially notable development has been occurring in the export sector. Accounting for three-fourths of total software revenue, the value of exports was US$8.5 billion. It also accounted for 8 percent of total Indian exports from in 20017. It is estimated that the software industry’s share of the total GDP was about 2 percent. A NASSCOM and McKinsey study projects that in 2008, Indian IT exports will total US$50 billion and comprise 35 percent of total exports. The study also projects that employment will increase to 2.2 million by 2008, compared with 280,000 in March 19998. Although the Indian share of total world software production is a meager 2 percent, India held 18.5 percent of the world customer software market in 19999. Indian software exports are mainly destined for the U.S. and Europe. In 1999, 62 percent of such exports went to North America, 23.5 percent to Europe was, and only 3.5 percent to. Japan. Can the Indian ICT industry continue to enjoy such remarkable growth? The above-mentioned projection by NASSCOM and McKinsey will be realized only if some pre-conditions are met. The first precondition is to supply sufficient infrastructure. Looking at Bangalore, the "Silicon Valley of India", one can question why it holds such a title. The road conditions are quite bad and electrical blackouts are an everyday affair. The second condition is to supply a sufficiently talented workforce. It is true that India has a fairly large number of people with suitable mathematics and English ability, yet the number of the English-speaking Indians occupies only 5 percent of the total population. Indians who are working in the U.S. are so to speak the elite of the elite, so without overcoming such fundamental bottlenecks, the Indian ICT industry will remain in a new kind of enclave in the future.

7

Nagesh Kumar, "Indian Software Industry Development: International and National Perspective,"

Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 36 No. 10, 2001. 8

NASSCOM, The IT Software and Services Industry in India: Strategic Review 2000, 2000, New

Delhi: NASSCOM. 9

Kumar, op.cit.

8

3. Future of India and Our Expectations 3-1 Problems to be solved Needless to say, today's India still has a lot of difficulties to solve, one of the most serious being the absolute deficiency infrastructure supply such as electricity, transportation, and roads. Another difficulty is India’s huge fiscal deficits. There is a strong possibility that the Indian government will fall into a debt trap. Thirdly, the annual growth rate for food grain production in 1990s stagnated at 1.7 percent; a much lower figure compared to the annual growth rate of 3.5 percent of the 1980s. Since the 1980s, there has appeared the so-called new middle class, who has enough income to buy cars, home electronics goods, and houses or flats. Moreover, the development of the Indian software industry is a well-known success story across the world and it can be said that India will be a big ICT power in near future. Nevertheless, India’s new middle class makes up only 10 percent of the total population at best, and the country still has the absolute poor who account for more than one fourth of the total population. If the ICT revolution further proceeds without resolving the problem of poverty, income disparities among Indian people or states will increase. As well, there is a strong possibility that environmental degradation and energy shortages would become more acute due to the population pressures. To sum up, the full-scale liberalization launched in 1992 is certainly changing the scenery of the Indian economy, but that change is checkered. Some very important reform programs in fields such as labor, agriculture, and the public sector have been left untouched, and as a result, the impacts of liberalization have also been checkered. Agenda and non-agenda economic reforms will continuously be the main issue that determines the future trajectory of Indian economic development, with the most difficult problem being the fight against the backwardness of society in order to expand social opportunities for the people10.

3-2 Looking Ahead Can India become a big economic power in the 21st century? Limiting the possibility of economic development from a long-term point of view, is India’s population size. The Indian population exceeded 1 billion in May 2000 and even today the annual population growth rate is 1.7 percent. It is projected that the population of India will supercede that of China around 2045 to become the world’s most populated country. At its peak, it is projected that the Indian population will be 1.5 to 1.7 billion. This is intense population pressure indeed. If we assume that India’s 6 to 6.5 percent annual economic growth rate continues for in the following decades, the per capita income will pass US$1,000 in around 2020. This figure would put

10

Jean Dreze and Amartya Sen, India: Development and Participation, Oxford: Oxford University

Press, 2002.

9

India into the category of a lower middle-income country, but coupled with factors such as the country’s huge population and excellent diplomatic ability, India would become a large Asian political and economic power, next to China. In 1998, the TIFAC (Technology Information, Forecasting and Assessment Council) report chaired by the Honorable Dr. Abdul Kalam, the President of India, outlined the vision of building "a strong India, a developed India and proud India" by establishing a technological basis.11 This vision is the same as ours. When Japanese started reconstruction and development following World War , we believed that technological development was the key to re-establishing the Japanese economy12. The Kalam report also projects the Indian income level for 2020, as presented in Table 12. According to this projection, per capita income of the poorest 10 percent will be US$569, and for the top 10 percent, it will be US$4,369. The national average is projected to be US$1,539 in 2020.

3-3 Our Expectations for India There is high probability that India will become a large political and economic power in not only Asia but also the world in the latter half of the 21st century. In addition, I also expect India to become a world leader of ideas. Modern India bore Mahatma Gandhi and Jawaharlal Nehru, both of whom were great philosophers and preeminent statesmen. We saw India with full respect and love in those days, and in the end, I believe it is not political, economic or military power per se that governs the world, but the power of ideas.

11

A. P. J. Abdul Kalam with Y. S. Rajan, India 2020: A Vision for the New Millennium, New Delhi:

Penguin Books. 12

Kalam cites an interesting story that was told by an elderly Indian businessman staying in a

Japanese hotel. "In the room where he [that businessman] stayed there was a leaking tap disturbed his sleep. He complained. Two people came to made it right. They apologized for the convenience caused to him and informed him of the hotel management's decision not to charge room rent. And then they showed the tap piece to him and said, 'Sir! Please see, the trouble caused to you is not by a Japanese product but an imported. We will continue to do better, Sir!" Dr. Kalam resumes this story that "the message is that most Japanese are proud of their country's capability. They want to excel in their work. If each of us attempts to do so in our spheres of work the status of developed India will arrive sooner than we expect." (A. P. J. Abdul Kalam and Y. S. Rajan, op.cit.)

10

Table 1 Trends of Real Economic Growth Rates Percent : At 1993-94 prices Year

Growth Rate of GNP

Growth Rate of Per Capita NNP

1991-92

1.1

- 1.5

1992-93

5.1

3.1

1993-94

5.9

3.4

1994-95

7.2

4.9

1995-96

7.5

5.2

1996-97

8.2

6.1

1997-98

4.9

2.6

1998-99

6.4

4.4

1999-2000

6.2

4.3

2000-01*

4.3

2.4

2001-02**

6.0

4.3

8th Plan Period (1992-97) average

6.8

4.6

9th Plan Period (1997-2002) average

5.6

3.6

*Provisional Estimates **Quick Estimates Source: GOI Economic Survey 2002-2003, p. S-4. Table 2 Gross Domestic Savings and Gross Domestic Capital Formation (Percent of GDP at current market prices) Year

GDS (1)

GDCF (2)

Savings-Investment Gap (1-2)

1990-91

23.1

26.3

-3.2

1991-92

22.0

22.6

-0.6

1992-93

21.8

23.6

-1.8

1993-94

22.5

23.1

-0.6

1994-95

24.8

26.0

-1.2

1995-96

25.1

26.9

-1.8

1996-97

23.2

24.5

-1.3

1997-98

23.1

24.6

-1.5

1998-99

21.5

22.6

-1.1

1999-2000

24.1

25.2

-1.1

2000-01*

23.4

24.0

-0.6

2001-02**

24.0

23.7

0.3

*Provisional estimates **Quick estimates Source: GOI Economic Survey 2002-2003, pp. S-8, S-9. 11

Table 3 Composition of GDS and GDCF (Percent of GDP at current market prices) Gross Domestic Savings

Gross Domestic Capital Formation

------------------------------------------------------------- ---------------------------------------Year

Household Sector

Private Corporate

Public

Total

Sector

Public Sector

Private

Total***

Sector

Sector 1991-92

17.0

3.1

2.0

22.0

8.8

13.1

22.6

1992-93

17.5

2.7

1.6

21.8

8.6

15.2

23.6

1993-94

18.4

3.5

0.6

22.5

8.2

13.0

23.1

1994-95

19.7

3.5

1.7

24.8

8.7

14.7

26.0

1995-96

18.2

4.9

2.0

25.1

7.7

18.9

26.9

1996-97

17.0

4.5

1.7

23.2

7.0

14.7

24.5

1997-98

17.6

4.2

1.3

23.1

6.6

16.0

24.6

1998-99

18.8

3.7

-1.0

21.5

6.6

14.8

22.6

1999-2000

20.8

4.4

-1.0

24.1

6.9

16.7

25.2

2000-01*

21.6

4.1

-2.3

23.4

6.4

16.1

24.0

2001-02**

22.5

4.0

-2.5

24.0

6.3

16.1

23.7

*Provisional estimates **Quick estimates ***Adjusted total Source: GOI Economic Survey 2002-2003 Table 4 Growth Rates of Industrial Production by Use-based Classification Year

Basic

Capital Intermediate Consumption Of which

Goods

Goods Goods

Goods

percent

(a)Consumer (b) Consumer Durables

Non-durables

1995-96

10.8

5.3

19.4

12.8

25.8

9.8

1996-97

3.0

11.5

8.1

6.2

4.6

6.6

1997-98

6.9

5.8

8.0

5.5

7.8

4.8

1998-99

1.6

12.6

6.1

2.2

5.6

1.2

1999-2000 5.5

6.9

8.8

5.7

14.1

3.2

2000-01

3.7

1.8

4.7

8.0

14.5

5.8

2001-02

2.6

-3.4

1.5

6.0

11.5

4.1

―――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――― Source: Government of India, Economic Survey 2002-2003, p.131.

12

Table 5 Increases of Market Size for Major Consumer Durables Rs. Crores ―――――――――――――――――――――――――――――― 1991

2001

―――――――――――――――――――――――――――――― Washing machines

8

PCs/Peripherals Cars

1,829

719

9,684

2,058

Television

228 times 13.5 times

16,443

1,382

8 times

7,420

5.4 times

―――――――――――――――――――――――――――――― Source: "Flying High," India Today International, August 11, 2003. Table 6 Balance of Payments (Percent of GDP) Year

Exports Imports Trade Balance

Invisible Balance

Current Account Balance

1995-96

9.1

12.3

-3.2

1.6

-1.7

1996-97

8.9

12.7

- 3.8

2.7

-1.2

1997-98

8.7

12.5

- 3.8

2.4

-1.4

1998-99

8.3

11.5

- 3.2

2.2

- 1.0

1999-2000

8.4

12.4

-4.0

3.0

-1.1

2000-01

9.8

13.0

-3.1

2.6

-0.5

2001-02

9.4

12.0

-2.6

2.9

0.3

Source: GOI Economic Survey 2002-2003, p.101. Table 7 Foreign Exchange Reserves (US $ million) 1992-93

9,832

1993-94

19,254

1994-95

25,186

1995-96

21,687

1996-97

26,423

1997-98

29,367

1998-99

32,490

1999-2000

38,036

2000-01

42,281

2001-02

54,106

December 2002

70,445

Source: GOI, Economic Survey 2002-2003, p. S-69.

13

Table 8 Foreign Investment Inflows (US$ million) ――――――――――――――――――――――――――――― Year

Direct Investment Portfolio Investment

Total

――――――――――――――――――――――――――――― 1991-92

129

4

133

1992-93

315

244

559

1993-94

586

3567

4153

1994-95

1314

3824

5138

1995-96

2144

2748

4892

1996-97

2821

3312

6133

1997-98

3557

1828

5385

1998-99

2462

-61

2401

1999-2000

2155

3026

5181

2000-01

2339

2760

5099

2001-02

3904

2021

5925

――――――――――――――――――――――――――――― Source: GOI Economic Survey 2002-2003, p. 119. Table 9 FDI Inflows in Selected Asian Economies US$ million ―――――――――――――――――――――――――― 1996

2001

―――――――――――――――――――――――――― China

40180

46846

India

2525

3403

Indonesia

6194

-3277

South Korea

2325

3198

Malaysia

7296

554

Philippines

1520

1792

Singapore

8608

8609

Thailand

2271

3759

―――――――――――――――――――――――――― Source: GOI Economic Survey 2002-2003, p. 120.

14

Table 10 Development of Indian Software Industry US$ million ―――――――――――――――――――――― Year

Total

Domestic

Exports

―――――――――――――――――――――― 1989-90

197

97

100

1994-95

835

350

485

1995-96

1224

490

734

1996-97

1755

670

1085

1997-98

2700

950

1750

1998-99

3900

1250

2650

1999-2000

5700

1700

4000

2000-01

8260

1960

6300

2001-02*

11200

2700

8500

―――――――――――――――――――――― * Projection Source: Nagesh Kumar, "Indian Software Industry Development". Table 11 India Vision 2002: Distribution of per capita GDP US$ ――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――― Income Class

1996

2000

2010

2020

――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――― Lowest 10

130.1

158.8

281.9

569.2

Next 10

169.2

206.0

365.7

738.5

2nd Quintile

212.8

259.7

461.0

930.8

3 Quintile

278.8

339.0

601.8

1215.4

4th Quintile

371.1

452.8

803.7

1623.1

749.1

914.2

1622.7

3277.1 4369.4

rd

th

5 Quintile Top 10

998.9

1218.9

2163.6

Overall

351.7

429.2

761.8

1538.5

―――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――― Source: A.P. J. Kalam with Y. S. Rajan, India 2002, p.16.

15

Related Documents

Esho Paper
December 2019 13
Paper
August 2019 42
Paper
October 2019 41
Paper
August 2019 43
Paper
November 2019 26
Paper
December 2019 25

More Documents from ""