Bifurcating Indemnification

  • Uploaded by: Boris Feldman
  • 0
  • 0
  • May 2020
  • PDF

This document was uploaded by user and they confirmed that they have the permission to share it. If you are author or own the copyright of this book, please report to us by using this DMCA report form. Report DMCA


Overview

Download & View Bifurcating Indemnification as PDF for free.

More details

  • Words: 908
  • Pages: 2
Bifurcating Indemnification by Boris Feldman[*] You are a director of a public company. You have fired an executive for misconduct. Her actions have embroiled the company in lawsuits, investigations, and government enforcement actions. She has hired her own lawyers. Her lawyers are running up huge bills and ignoring the General Counsel’s requests for budgets and restraint. The General Counsel advises you that the ex-employee’s fees could amount to millions of dollars, and that the company is obligated to pay them. Is there anything you can do to stop this travesty? Probably not. Nearly every public company has adopted expansive indemnification policies for its officers and directors. Most are governed by Delaware law. Those of other jurisdictions are similar. The indemnification provisions are embodied in bylaws and sometimes in separate indemnification agreements. At its core, the typical indemnification provision obligates the company to pay for an executive’s lawyer to represent her in connection with any conduct within the scope of her employment. Indemnification continues after termination of employment for conduct prior to the termination. Indemnification continues even if the Board fires the executive. The executive is usually required to sign an undertaking agreeing to repay the fees that were advanced if a court later determines that indemnification was not permitted. The circumstances under which indemnification is barred are rare: typically, proof that an employee engaged in unlawful conduct and did not believe that it was in the best interests of the company. For example, an employee who embezzled from the company bank account would probably not be eligible for indemnification. On the other hand, an employee who falsified revenue to improve the company’s reported results probably would be. Regardless of whether the employee is ultimately found to have been entitled to indemnification, the key point is this: during the course of the litigation – including any dispute as to right to indemnification – the company continues to pay. The approach is “pay first, litigate later.” In theory, the company can later recoup the advanced payments from the executive after proving that indemnification was not permitted. But, good luck finding the assets to recoup (especially after the executive has had to deal with class actions, SEC proceedings, and so on). The modern approach to indemnification seems overboard, until one recalls its historical roots: the Vandal hordes. The scenario for which indemnification agreements are designed is this: your company has been taken over in a hostile tender offer. The acquirer has fired everyone and is determined to deprive them of everything to which they are entitled. The acquirer denies indemnification on meritless grounds. But the practical effect is that the former executive cannot pay for counsel and surrenders. In this scenario, the modern indemnification structure makes sense. To protect corporate officers and directors, they must know that they cannot be arbitrarily denied the right to defend themselves. In effect, the system presumes bad faith on the part of the board seeking to withhold indemnification, because today’s board was yesterday’s barbarians at the gates. The bias toward former employees, which makes much sense in the context of a change on control, makes no sense absent a change in control. The legal system routinely defers to a Board’s business judgment. Why should we not defer to the Board when it decides that a fired executive’s conduct does not merit

indemnification? In my opinion, it is time for companies to consider adopting bifurcated indemnification provisions. Current board indemnification would apply in the event of a change in control. Although there are various ways to define “change in control,” corporate lawyers have great experience in doing so in connection with employment agreements, poison pills, and other provisions. Absent a change in control, the Board could withhold indemnification for cause. This does not necessarily mean that the employee was terminated for cause: often, executives are separated for doing something wrong (or not doing something right) without labeling it a for-cause termination. Rather, the Board would make a determination that, for particular reasons, indemnification was not appropriate or in the best interests of the company. Those grounds could either be set forth in the bylaws or agreements, or developed by the Board on a case-by-case basis. For example: “Notwithstanding the foregoing, the Board may withhold indemnification where it concludes that the employee has acted in a manner that she knew or reasonably should have known was detrimental to the interests of the company.” But wait, an executive might cry: how can I trust the Board to treat me fairly? The answer is that Boards exercise broad discretion under the business judgment rule all the time. There is no reason to deny them that discretion with respect to decisions involving millions of dollars for the Company. If the executive denied indemnification believes that she has been treated unfairly, she can always seek judicial recourse – but without the company footing the bill in the interim. Presumably, it would be the rare case in which a Board denied indemnification. But that decision is properly made based on the facts of each situation, so long as the extant Board remains in place and has not been ousted by a group intent on wreaking vengeance on the prior executive team. [*] *Copyright 2007. Boris Feldman is a member of Wilson Sonsini Goodrich & Rosati. This article reflects his views, not his firm's. You are welcome to copy and distribute this article, with express attribution to the author. Revised, February 10, 2007.

Related Documents


More Documents from "Boris Feldman"