United
States
Drug
Policy
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
Alec
Johnston
(ID#
25729)
–
Erfurt
School
of
Public
Policy
–
2009
A
thesis
submitted
in
partial
fulfillment
of
the
requirements
for
the
degree
of
Master
of
Public
Policy
Thesis
Supervisor:
Dr.
Heike
Grimm
Erfurt,
July
17,
2009
Erfurt
School
of
Public
Policy
–
University
of
Erfurt
–
Nordhäuser
Str.
63
–
D‐99089
www.espp.de
‐
publicpolicy@uni‐erfurt.de
ABSTRACT
The
purpose
of
this
document
is
to
consider
the
effectiveness
of
the
current
U.S.
drug
policy
over
the
last
30
years
and
to
offer
an
answer
to
the
question:
How
can
U.S.
drug
policy
be
improved?
The
document
considers
drug
policy
in
light
of
the
economic
effects
of
prohibition,
the
history
of
drug
policy
in
the
U.S.
over
the
relevant
period,
the
policies
of
other
countries
that
have
been
more
entrepreneurial
in
their
creation
of
drug
policies
like
the
Netherlands
and
Portugal.
The
Document
then
discusses
the
current
events
and
discussions
taking
place
regarding
drug
policy
in
America.
Next
the
paper
discusses
three
possible
policy
frameworks
that
could
be
adopted
to
address
the
issue:
legalization,
decriminalization,
and
depenalization.
Finally
a
concrete
policy
proposal
is
offered
as
a
possible
strategy
to
improve
the
drug
situation
in
the
United
States.
ZUSAMMENFASSUNG
Das
Ziel
der
vorliegenden
Masterarbeit
besteht
darin,
die
Effektivität
der
US‐ Amerikanischen
Drogenpolitik
zu
verbessern.
Die
gegenwärtige
Drogenpolitik
wird
im
Rückblick
auf
die
letzten
30
Jahre
analysiert.
Im
Mittelpunkt
der
Arbeit
steht
demnach
eine
zentrale
Frage:
Wie
kann
die
Drogenpolitik
der
Vereinigten
Staaten
verbessert
werden?
Die
Arbeit
diskutiert
die
Drogenpolitik
im
Lichte
ökonomischer
Effekte,
gibt
einen
Rückblick
auf
die
Entwicklung
der
Drogenpolitik
im
relevanten
Zeitraum
und
zeigt
an
Hand
von
Länderbeispielen
–
Niederlande
und
Portugal
–
eine
stärkeren
unternehmerischen
Ansatz
der
Drogenpolitik
auf.
Im
Anschluss
werden
die
aktuellen
Ereignisse
und
Diskussionen
in
den
USA
erörtert
sowie
nachfolgend
drei
Handlungsszenarien
beschrieben,
die
realisiert
werden
könnten.
In
allen
Szenarien
werden
einige
Kernpunkte
aufgegriffen:
Legalisierung,
Entkriminalisierung
und
Depenalisierung.
Schlussfolgernd
wird
eine
konkrete
Handlungsempfehlung
gegeben
‐
eine
Strategie,
zur
Verbesserung
der
Drogensituation
in
den
Vereinigten
Staaten.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
2
Table
of
Contents
INTRODUCTION
4
1.
AN
ANALYSIS
OF
THE
EFFECTS
OF
PROHIBITION
7
1.1
FOREIGN
EFFECTS
1.2
MONETARY
EFFECTS
OF
PROHIBITION
1.3
SUBSTITUTION
1.4
CORRUPTION
1.5
ADULTERATION
AND
POTENCY
1.6
SOCIAL
COSTS:
CRIME
1.7
SECTION
SUMMARY
9
10
13
14
15
16
17
2.
RECENT
HISTORY
OF
THE
WAR
ON
DRUGS
18
2.1
FOREIGN
ISSUES
2.2
MONETARY
COSTS
2.3
CORRUPTION
2.4
SOCIAL
CLASS
EFFECTS
2.5
IMPRISONMENT
2.6
ANALYSIS
OF
THE
EFFECTIVENESS
OF
THE
ONDCP
2.7
SECTION
SUMMARY
25
28
29
31
34
35
38
3.
HARM
REDUCTION
SUCCESSES
IN
FOREIGN
COUNTRIES
39
3.1
THE
CASE
OF
HOLLAND
3.2
THE
CASE
OF
PORTUGAL
41
45
4.
CURRENT
ISSUES,
EVENTS,
AND
FACTORS
RELEVANT
TO
THE
DRUG
POLICY
DISCUSSION
49
4.1
CURRENT
TRENDS
4.2
MEDICAL
MARIJUANA
4.3
FOREIGN
IMPACT
OF
DRUG
PROHIBITION:
CURRENT
DEVELOPMENTS
IN
MEXICO
50
56
60
5.
POTENTIAL
POLICY
FRAMEWORKS
65
5.1
POLICY
FRAMEWORK
OPTION:
LEGALIZATION
5.2
POLICY
FRAMEWORK
OPTION:
DECRIMINALIZATION
5.3
POLICY
FRAMEWORK
OPTION:
DEPENALIZATION
67
70
72
6.
POLICY
RECOMMENDATION
72
CONCLUSION
77
BIBLIOGRAPHY
78
ERKLÄRUNG
83
United
States
Drug
Policy
3
Introduction
In
American
civil
discourse
the
subject
of
drug
policy
is
one
that
arouses
intense
passion
from
all
sides
involved
in
the
debate
with
respect
to
which
policy
would
be
best.
What
should
the
objectives
of
a
rational
drug
control
policy
be?
Should
drug
use
prevention
or
harm
reduction
be
the
dominant
ideology
that
informs
national
policy‐makers?
What
are
the
full
implications
of
the
current
policy;
how
well
does
it
achieve
its
objectives,
and
would
an
alternate
policy
be
better
suited
to
achieving
those
objectives
regardless
of
what
particular
message
we
believe
the
policy
sends?
These
are
all
very
difficult
questions
to
answer
as
Americans
begin
a
new
chapter
of
their
storied
drug
policy
history;
a
history
we
will
have
to
unravel
in
order
to
evaluate
the
efficacy
of
the
current
policy
and
to
recommend
how
this
policy
can
be
improved
in
light
of
the
stated
objectives.
The
purpose
of
this
paper
will
be
to
answer
the
question:
How
should
US
drug
policy
be
reformed?
This
question
may
seem
biased
in
that
it
presupposes
that
the
current
drug
policy
is
somehow
flawed
and
in
order
to
explain
that
presupposition
we
must
first
analyze
prohibition,
which
will
provide
a
general
framework
through
which
one
can
make
certain
assumptions
about
the
likely
effects
of
further
prohibition.
In
order
to
accomplish
this
goal,
this
section
will
examine
the
effects
of
alcohol
Prohibition
in
the
early
20th
century,
and
what
we
know
about
the
effects
of
drug
prohibition
in
the
US,
which
actually
began
before
alcohol
Prohibition.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
4
The
following
section
will
be
devoted
to
explaining
just
how
badly
the
policy
needs
reformed
in
light
of
the
policy’s
stated
objectives.
This
section
will
focus
on
the
era
of
drug
policy
reform
that
began
after
1979,
the
year
of
all‐time
highs
regarding
drug
usage,
and
for
the
organizational
purposes
of
this
study
this
period
will
be
assumed
to
have
ended
with
the
beginning
of
the
Obama
era.
Effects
to
be
examined
include,
but
are
not
limited
to,
the
effects
of
prohibition
on:
crime
rates,
availability
of
prohibited
substances,
potency
of
prohibited
substances,
substitution
of
prohibited
substances,
and
the
continued
use
of
prohibited
substances.
The
generalizations
made
in
this
section
will
inform
our
further
discussion
and
recommendations.
A
study
of
US
drug
policy
would
be
incomplete
without
a
discussion
of
some
of
the
practices
of
other
countries.
Some
have
criticized
the
applicability
of
country
case
studies
by
attacking
their
relevance
in
light
of
cultural
differences,
and
the
difficulty
in
gleaning
best
practices
from
such
studies.
This
author
believes
that
the
applicability
of
country
case
studies
is
potentially
useful,
at
least
insofar
as
one
can
see
how
different
policies
are
administered
and
the
effects
those
policies
have
had.
The
examples
provided
by
both
the
Netherlands
and
Portugal,
and
Switzerland
to
a
very
small
degree,
will
be
discussed
so
that
the
reader
can
imagine
a
policy
that
focuses
on
harm
reduction
instead
of
usage
prevention.
In
the
next
section
we
will
further
discuss
the
current
developments
regarding
drug
policy
in
the
US.
These
developments
will
include
those
from
the
beginning
of
2009
and
some
information
about
the
administration’s
attitude
toward
the
subject
and
the
likelihood
of
major
reform
during
United
States
Drug
Policy
5
Obama’s
presidency.
Also
in
this
section
we
will
discuss
information
pertaining
to
various
state
policy
developments,
medical
marijuana,
and
the
international
drug
trafficking
crisis
that
is
emerging
in
Mexico.
The
next
section
will
provide
an
analysis
of
three
policy
framework
options
that
could
conceivably
be
adopted
by
the
Obama
administration,
along
with
a
discussion
of
their
likelihood
of
acceptance.
We
will
further
examine
the
various
concerned
stakeholders
in
this
section,
and
their
impact
on
the
reform
process.
The
first
policy
framework
to
be
discussed
is
legalization,
or
the
libertarian
approach.
This
is
necessary
to
provide
an
understanding
of
how
a
free
market
in
drugs
would
affect
the
various
factors
we
are
concerned
with
such
as
violence,
drug
usage,
financial
cost
and
social
effects.
The
next
policy
framework
to
be
examined
is
the
decriminalization
of
presently
prohibited
substances.
This
option
is
more
likely
to
be
accepted
because
it
retains
penalties
for
trafficking
and
possession
for
personal
use,
but
these
penalties
are
redefined
as
administrative
offenses
punishable
by
the
imposition
of
a
fine
and
a
treatment
option.
The
final
policy
framework
to
be
analyzed
will
be
also
the
most
likely
one
to
be
accepted
for
a
variety
of
reasons:
depenalization,
which
maintains
the
classification
of
offenses
as
criminal,
but
precludes
prison
terms
for
possession
for
personal
use.
Each
of
these
policies
has
its
strengths
and
weaknesses,
which
will
be
discussed.
The
final
section
of
this
paper
will
consist
of
a
concrete
policy
recommendation,
which
addresses
the
various
shortcomings
of
the
current
policy
and
attempts
to
ameliorate
them
in
a
way
that
is
both
bold,
considering
the
trajectory
of
drug
policy
over
the
last
30
years,
and
possible,
considering
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
6
the
new
attitude
in
Washington
after
the
election
of
Barack
Obama
and
the
increasing
support
for
drug
policy
reform
among
the
electorate
in
the
U.S.
1.
An
Analysis
of
the
Effects
of
Prohibition
In
order
to
begin
a
discussion
about
prohibition,
one
must
first
define
the
term:
Prohibition
will
be
defined
for
the
purpose
of
this
paper
as
a
government
decree
against
the
exchange
of
a
good
or
a
service.1
The
goal
of
prohibition
is
to
prevent
people
from
trading
in
the
prohibited
market
by
making
the
product
scarce,
more
expensive,
less
safe,
and
by
introducing
uncertainty
into
the
market.
Thus
prohibition
is
a
supply‐side
policy,
and
it
has
a
miniscule
effect
on
demand
because
prohibition
does
nothing
to
change
the
actual
tastes
of
consumers.2
The
drug
war,
and
its
supporting
claims
can
best
be
summarized
by
the
following
four
points:
“illegal
drugs
are:
(1)
always
bad;
(2)
never
acceptable;
(3)
supply‐driven;
and
(4)
must
be
fought
through
an
ongoing
war.”3
In
practice,
however,
prohibitions
in
America
have
often
been
implemented
in
an
attempt
to
penalize
the
users
when
the
majority
of
users
of
a
particular
substance
constitute
a
racial
minority.4
The
prohibition
of
opium
initially
targeted
Chinese;
the
prohibition
of
marijuana
initially
targeted
Mexicans;
and
the
prohibition
of
or
increased
penalties
for
crack
cocaine
targeted
African
Americans.5
In
fact,
while
deliberating
the
1
Mark
Thornton,
The
Economics
of
Prohibition
(Salt
Lake
City:
University
of
Utah
Press,
1991),
3.
2
Thornton,
The
Economics
of
Prohibition,
74.
3
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
9.
4
Matthew
B.Robinson
and
Renee
G.
Scherlen,Lies,
Damned
Lies,
and
Drug
War
Statistics
(Albany:
State
University
of
New
York
Press,
2007),
12.
5
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
13.
United
States
Drug
Policy
7
passage
of
the
Harrison
Act
in
1914,
congressmen
argued
that
the
opium
trade
was
part
of
a
deliberate
effort
of
the
Chinese
to
undermine
American
society.6
Additionally,
H.R.
Haldeman,
President
Nixon’s
chief
of
staff
once
quoted
the
president,
who
initiated
the
drug
war
in
1972,
as
saying
“You
have
to
face
the
fact
that
the
whole
problem
is
really
the
blacks.
The
key
is
to
devise
a
system
that
recognizes
this
all
the
while
not
appearing
to.”7
While
the
drug
war
may
not
be
fought
today
for
racial
reasons,
clearly
the
strategies
used
disproportionately
affect
minorities,
specifically
African
Americans.
The
first
effect
of
prohibition
we
will
discuss
is
its
effect
on
the
establishment
of
a
black
market.
Black
markets
emerge
because
of
the
profit
opportunities
provided
by
state
prohibitions
on
many
products,
including
drugs,
firearms,
child
pornography,
and
even
radar
detectors
in
some
cases.
That
there
is
a
market
for
such
products
is
indisputable;
no
state
prohibition
can
prevent
people
from
attempting
to
maximize
their
own
personal
utility
as
they
measure
it.
Some
might
argue
that
drug
use
is
irrational,
because
it
has
no
discernable
benefit
to
the
user,
or
to
society,
but
this
argument
is
flawed
because
value
is
subjective
and
also
varies
through
time.
The
argument
that
the
irrationality
of
addicted
users
makes
prohibition
necessary
is
also
flawed
because
addicts
represent
a
minority
of
all
illicit
substance
users
and
the
majority
of
the
population
has
rejected
this
argument
with
respect
to
alcohol
and
even
tobacco,
which
is
more
addictive
than
heroin.8
That
drug
6
Cathy
Lisa
Schneider,
“Racism,
Drug
Policy,
and
AIDS,”
Political
Science
Quarterly
113,
no.
3
(1998):
434.
7
Leonard
Pitts
Jr.,
“Begin
Discussion
on
Legalizing
Drugs,”
Miami
Herald
(Mar.
31,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.miamiherald.com/living/columnists/leonard‐ pitts/story/978041.html
8
Anonymous,
The
Case
for
Legalization,
2.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
8
consumers
use
drugs
is
proof
that
they
derive
some
benefit
from
the
use
of
drugs:
prohibition
only
ensures
that
an
illegal
market
supplies
the
illicit
goods.
In
the
Unites
States,
the
most
well
known
prohibition
is
not
narcotics
prohibition,
which
began
in
1914
with
the
passage
of
the
Harrison
Act,
but
alcohol
Prohibition,
which
began
in
1917
with
the
passage
of
the
18th
Amendment,
and
ended
in
1933
with
the
passage
of
the
21st
Amendment.9
The
fact
that
alcohol
Prohibition
is
more
widely
discussed
may
be
indicative
of
the
fact
that
there
were,
and
are,
far
more
alcohol
users
than
narcotics
users,
and
that
the
majority
does
not
view
alcohol
consumption
as
dangerous
or
morally
wrong,
which
seems
to
be
the
majority
opinion
concerning
today’s
illicit
drugs.
To
be
sure,
alcohol
Prohibition
did
in
fact
decrease
the
consumption
of
alcohol:
Consumption
rapidly
decreased
at
the
onset
of
Prohibition
to
about
30
percent
of
its
pre‐Prohibition
level.10
Consumption
increased
over
the
next
few
years,
however,
to
60‐70
percent
of
its
pre‐ Prohibition
level,
where
it
stabilized
until
the
end
of
Prohibition.11
After
the
abolition
of
Prohibition,
consumption
levels
initially
remained
stable
and
then
increased
to
their
pre‐Prohibition
level
over
the
following
decade.12
1.1
Foreign
Effects
The
black
market
created
by
Prohibition
was
worth
millions
of
dollars
and
the
long
U.S.‐Mexico
border
became
an
ideal
place
to
smuggle
alcohol
and
9
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
23.
10
Jeffrey
A.
Miron
and
Jeffrey
Zwiebel,
“Alcohol
Consumption
During
Prohibition,”
The
American
Economic
Review
81,
no.
2
(1991):
242.
11
Jeffrey
A.
Miron
and
Jeffrey
Zwiebel,
“Alcohol
Consumption,”
242.
12
Jeffrey
A.
Miron
and
Jeffrey
Zwiebel,
“Alcohol
Consumption,”
242.
United
States
Drug
Policy
9
other
drugs
into
the
U.S.13
The
Mexican
beer
industry
flourished
and
by
1923
it
was
reported
that
this
industry
was
second
in
importance
within
the
Mexican
economy.14
As
the
beer
industry
expanded
to
fill
the
gap
left
by
previous
imported
American
beer,
hard
liquor
began
to
be
smuggled
into
the
U.S.
across
the
border
and
also
along
the
Pacific
and
Gulf
coasts,
and
it
continued
to
be
throughout
the
entire
period
of
Prohibition.15
The
knowledge
gained
during
Prohibition
was
useful
even
after
1933,
and
the
distribution
channels
still
exist
today;
it
is
clear
that
substance
prohibition
also
has
profound
effects
on
foreign
countries.16
During
Prohibition
a
large
quantity
of
alcohol
was
also
smuggled
into
the
United
States
from
Canada,
and
was
distributed
throughout
the
Northern
U.S.
One
lesson
that
can
be
learned
from
Prohibition
is
that
regulations
adopted
by
one
country
necessarily
have
effects
in
other
countries.
In
the
case
of
a
prohibition,
the
profit
potential
proves
irresistible,
and
foreign
smugglers
go
to
great
lengths
to
realize
those
profits.
This
factor
should
be
considered
in
any
discussion
of
drug
policy
as
a
negative
external
effect
in
adjacent
countries.
1.2
Monetary
Effects
of
Prohibition
Monetary
costs
to
consumers,
producers,
and
to
society
increase
for
a
number
of
reasons
in
a
prohibited
market.
Consumer
prices
in
a
prohibited
market
reflect
increased
supply
costs,
which
are
due
to
the
fact
that
suppliers
must
avoid
detection,
and
include
a
risk
premium
that
is
the
result
of
13
Gabriela
Recio,
“Drugs
and
Alcohol:
US
Prohibition
and
the
Origins
of
the
Drug
Trade
in
Mexico,”
Journal
of
Latin
American
Studies
34,
no.
3
(2002):
27.
14
Gabriela
Recio,
“Drugs
and
Alcohol,”
32.
15
Gabriela
Recio,
“Drugs
and
Alcohol,”
33.
16
Gabriela
Recio,
“Drugs
and
Alcohol,”
42.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
10
potential
punishment.17
In
addition,
competitive
drug
markets
also
include
production
costs,
the
cost
of
dealing
or
distributing,
and
transportation
costs,
which
are
associated
with
markets
for
every
good.18
Prohibition
distorts
supply
and
demand
equilibrium
by
shifting
the
supply
curve
upward,
and
the
demand
curve
downward,
albeit
to
a
far
lesser
degree.19
This
occurs
because
the
producers
are
subjected
to
the
increased
transaction
costs
mentioned
above,
and
are
more
likely
to
be
targets
of
violence
than
casual
users
are.20
Due
to
the
illegal
nature
of
these
goods,
these
normal
characteristics
of
market
participation
are
more
expensive
due
to
the
need
to
operate
clandestinely.
Economists
who
analyze
the
Drug
War
often
refer
to
the
effects
of
enforcement
as
a
“tax”
on
consumers,
but
the
illicit
suppliers
collect
the
tax
instead
of
the
government.21
In
the
case
of
alcohol
Prohibition,
economists
have
estimated
that
prices
increased
by
about
three
times,
and,
in
the
present
Drug
War,
cocaine
prices
are
at
a
minimum
20
times
more
expensive
than
if
the
good
was
available
in
the
free
market.22
Some
drug
prohibition
experts
argue
that
a
drug
price
analysis
should
compare
black
market
prices
to
prices
that
would
be
found
in
a
state
regulated
market
because,
they
argue,
this
is
the
most
likely
alternative
to
the
current
regime.23
While
it
is
certainly
true
that
prices
in
a
regulated
market
17
Miron
and
Zwiebel,
“Alcohol
Consumption,”
245.
18
Kai
A.
Konrad,
“Drug
Policy
and
Federalism,”
Public
Choice
80,
no.
1/2
(1994):
57.
19
Jeffrey
A.
Miron
and
Jeffrey
Zwiebel,
“The
Economic
Case
Against
Drug
Prohibition,”
The
Journal
of
Economic
Perspectives
9,
no.
4
(1995):
176.
20
Miron
and
Zwiebel
“The
Economic
Case”
176.
21
Nadelmann,
“A
Bad
Export,”
85.
22
Miron
and
Zwiebel
“The
Economic
Case”
177.
23
Jeffrey
A.
Miron,
“The
Effect
of
Drug
Prohibition
on
Drug
Prices:
Evidence
from
the
Markets
for
Cocaine
and
Heroin,”
The
Review
of
Economics
and
Statistics
85,
no.
3
(2003):
522.
United
States
Drug
Policy
11
are
higher
than
in
an
unregulated
free
market,
this
fact
does
not
preclude
the
analytical
value
of
considering
a
free
market
regime;
both
are
important
hypothetical
scenarios
from
which
hypothetical
market
characteristics,
including
price
trends,
can
be
readily
deduced.
One
inevitable
characteristic
of
a
regulated
market
for
these
substances
would
be
the
imposition
of
a
tax.
If
the
markets
for
cigarettes
or
tobacco
are
any
indication,
sin
taxes
can
increase
the
price
of
a
good
by
as
much
as
three
hundred
percent
without
creating
a
black
market.24
However,
as
cigarette
taxes
have
increased
over
the
years
a
black
market
has
developed,
and
the
Bureau
of
Alcohol,
Tobacco
and
Firearms
estimates
that
approximately
$5
billion
in
tax
revenue
is
lost
annually
due
to
cigarette
traffickers.25
This
indicates
that
there
are
limits
to
the
severity
of
sin
taxes
of
legal
goods
as
well,
so
the
success
of
a
liberalized
drug
market
would
depend
on
the
level
of
associated
taxation.
In
today’s
black
market,
all
echelons
of
the
drug
trade
avoid
taxes
due
to
the
illegality
of
their
activities,
which
should
be
considered
in
the
comparison
between
the
different
hypothetical
markets.26
In
fact,
some
states
like
Kansas
actually
require
drug
dealers
to
purchase
tax
stamps
for
their
products
notwithstanding
the
fact
that
these
substances
are
illegal.
In
the
event
that
these
stamps
are
not
purchased
and
the
activities
are
discovered,
the
dealer
faces
increased
penalties
for
tax
evasion.27
24
Miron,
“Effect
of
Drug
Prohibition
on
Drug
Prices,”
525.
25
Elfrink,
BlackMarket
Cigarettes:
Miami’s
New
Vice
26
Miron,
“Effect
of
Drug
Prohibition
on
Drug
Prices,”
522.
27
Anonymous,
“Drug
Tax
Stamp,”
Kansas
Department
of
Revenue
(2009
[cited
15
Jul.
2009])
available
from
http://www.ksrevenue.org/perstaxtypesdrug.htm
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
12
1.3
Substitution
One
unintended
consequence
of
prohibition
is
substitution,
or
substance
displacement.
Because
a
user’s
utility
is
determined
through
the
simple
formula
of
satisfaction
derived
minus
costs,
the
use
of
a
particular
substance
can
become
cost
prohibitive.28
In
the
event
that
one
substance
becomes
too
expensive
or
risky,
consumers
and
suppliers
will
migrate
to
other
substances
that
are
cheaper,
less
risky,
and
possibly
even
completely
unknown
to
authorities.29
Some
evidence
suggests
that
during
Prohibition
the
use
of
both
opiates
and
marijuana
increased,
perhaps
because
their
relative
risk
was
decreased
because
of
the
focus
on
alcohol
enforcement.30
The
case
of
the
drug
“foxy”
is
illustrative:
this
drug
was
common
earlier
in
this
decade
among
young
adults
and
teenagers
for
its
hallucinogenic
effect,
but
was
wholly
unknown
to
enforcement
officials
until
2003
when
the
DEA
scheduled
the
drug
as
a
controlled
substance.
In
this
way
drug
entrepreneurs
are
able
to
create
new
drugs,
with
effects
similar
to
existing
drugs,
and
avoid
prosecution
in
the
short
run
because
these
new
drugs
are
not
yet
prohibited.
Users
may
also
migrate
to
legal
drugs
like
tobacco
or
alcohol
in
the
event
that
their
drug
of
choice
becomes
too
risky
or
expensive,
often
with
greater
health
risks
for
themselves
and
for
society.
28
Jonathan
P.
Caulkins,
“Zero‐Tolerance
Policies:
Do
They
Inhibit
of
Stimulate
Illicit
Drug
Consumption,”
Management
Science
39,
no.
4
(1993):
46.
29
Anonymous,
“2008
World
Drug
Report,”
United
Nations
Office
on
Drugs
and
Crime
(2008),
editied
by
Sandeep
Chawlap:
available
from
www.unodc.org/documents/wdr/...2008/WDR_2008_eng_web.pdf:
21.
30
Miron
and
Zwiebel
“The
Economic
Case,”
183.
United
States
Drug
Policy
13
1.4
Corruption
Corruption
is
a
well‐known
effect
of
substance
prohibition.
Corruption
could
be
considered
as
a
general
cost
of
government
intervention,
which
is
caused
by
the
illegal
sale
of
property
rights
by
government
officials
to
private
individuals.31
Drug
traffickers
are
able
to
offer
public
officials,
from
border
agents
to
federal
judges,
compensation
in
an
amount
greater
than
their
annual
salary
for
something
as
trivial
as
looking
the
other
way
or
not
interfering
in
a
transaction.32
In
the
event
that
monetary
compensation
is
insufficient,
traffickers
may
resort
to
threatening
officials,
their
families
or
their
property
in
an
attempt
to
force
cooperation.
Not
only
direct
prohibition
contributes
to
corruption:
Before
Prohibition,
saloon
keepers
faced
increasing
regulation
as
a
result
of
their
reputation
as
places
where
the
poor,
working
and
immigrant
classes
congregated.33
Saloons
were
faced
with
increasing
annual
license
fees,
which
caused
saloon‐owners
to
keep
their
establishments
open
on
Sundays
in
violation
of
Blue
Laws:
To
avoid
fines
for
this
offense
many
saloon‐owners
bribed
police
and
other
elected
officials.34
In
this
way
the
reputation
of
saloons
was
tarnished
and
associated
with
corruption
even
though
laws
and
regulations
practically
forced
owners
to
break
the
law
or
to
close
up
shop.
There
are
many
theories
that
attempt
to
explain
corruption,
however,
two
facts
about
corruption
seem
to
be
abundantly
clear:
first,
that
corruption
is
directly
related
to
the
price,
or
loss
inflicted,
of
the
prohibition
and
indirectly
to
the
level
of
enforcement;
and
31
Thornton,
The
Economics
of
Prohibition,
129.
32
Ethan
A.
Nadelmann,
“U.S.
Drug
Policy:
A
Bad
Export,”
Foreign
Policy
70,
no.
25
(1988):
86.
33
Thornton,
The
Economics
of
Prohibition,
54.
34
Thornton,
The
Economics
of
Prohibition,
54.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
14
second,
corruption
exists
in
all
areas
where
government
attempts
to
enforce
victimless
crime
laws.35
1.5
Adulteration
and
Potency
Prohibition
of
substances
tends
to
increase
their
potency
over
time.
During
alcohol
Prohibition,
the
consumption
of
beer
and
wine
fell
dramatically,
while
the
consumption
of
spirits,
moonshine,
and
white
lightening
skyrocketed
because
it
makes
sense
to
buy
prohibited
substances
in
concentrated
form
as
a
way
to
decrease
risk
per
unit
of
intoxicant.36
In
addition
to
an
increase
in
average
drug
potency
over
time,
another
characteristic
of
a
black
market
in
illicit
substances
is
increased
uncertainty
about
potency
and
quality
at
any
given
time.37
Naturally
one
cannot
file
a
complaint
with
a
consumer
protection
organization,
no
government
quality
regulations
exist
for
these
products,
and
a
normal
reputation
market
does
not
exist.38
Due
to
the
illicit
and
uncertain
market,
dealers
and
other
members
of
the
distribution
chain
are
occasionally
faced
with
the
prospect
of
having
to
find
new
sources
of
product.
In
these
cases
it
is
possible
that
the
product
quality
differs
from
the
previous
supply
and
that
consumers
are
placed
at
risk
because
of
their
lack
of
awareness
of
the
source
of
the
supply
or
the
production
practices.
This
differs
from
a
free,
or
even
regulated,
market,
which
would
be
characterized
by
increasing
certainty
and
improving
quality
over
time.
35
Thornton,
The
Economics
of
Prohibition,
133.
36
Anonymous,
The
Case
for
Legalization,
2
37
Miron
and
Zwiebel,
“The
Economic
Case,”
179.
38
Miron
and
Zwiebel,
“The
Economic
Case,”
179.
United
States
Drug
Policy
15
Drug
policy
experts
have
concluded
that
increased
enforcement
actually
tends
to
increase
the
average
potency
of
illicit
drugs.39
This
strategy
is
employed
to
make
enforcement
less
effective,
and
the
strategy
is
effective
because
drug
penalties
are
defined
by
the
quantity
of
substance
seized
by
enforcement
officials,
therefore,
increasing
the
potency
of
drugs
decreases
the
risk
per
unit
of
intoxicant.
In
addition,
potency
increases
to
combat
any
increase
in
enforcement,
and,
in
this
case,
danger
to
the
consumer
also
increases
because
their
expectations
for
a
product
with
a
certain
potency
level
are
erroneous
causing
them
to
consume
unexpected
units
of
intoxicant
endangering
themselves.
1.6
Social
Costs:
Crime
Some
advocates
of
prohibition
contend
that
the
use
of
illegal
substances
leads
to
increased
social
costs
due
to
crime.
In
fact,
many
point
to
crimes
committed
by
users
of
cocaine
and
heroin
as
the
best
examples,
however,
the
crime
caused
by
these
two
drugs
is
miniscule
compared
to
the
crime
caused
by
alcohol
use.40
It
is
true
that
a
correlation
exists
between
the
price
of
heroin
and
crime,
but
this
crime
is
more
logically
attributable
to
prohibition
prices,
which
force
addicted
users
with
an
inelastic
demand
curve
to
occasionally
resort
to
crime
to
fund
their
addiction.41
In
addition
to
the
crime
caused
by
addicts
looking
to
get
their
fix,
the
very
nature
of
prohibition
encourages
criminality.
Because
of
the
illicit
nature
of
trading
in
black
markets,
courts
cannot
be
used
to
resolve
disputes.
Because
of
this,
in
the
39
Thornton,
The
Economics
of
Prohibition,
56.
40
Konrad,
Drug
Policy
and
Federalism,
56.
41
Konrad,
Drug
Policy
and
Federalism,
57.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
16
black
market,
where
force
must
be
used
to
protect
turf,
enforce
contracts,
and
punish
informants,
violence
and
the
predisposition
to
committing
violent
acts
are
valued
attributes.42
Any
analysis
of
the
effects
of
prohibition
on
total
criminality
would
be
incomplete
without
considering
the
opportunity
costs
associated
with
enforcement.
The
biggest
cost
of
enforcing
drug
laws
is
the
realignment
of
police
priorities
toward
fighting
the
drug
war
at
the
expense
of
the
prevention
and
investigation
of
other
crimes.43
Some
evidence
also
exists
that
suggests
prohibition
has
a
more
direct
effect
on
crime:
Crime
increased
dramatically
throughout
the
1920s
as
the
number
of
prisoners
in
federal
prisons,
reformatories,
and
camps
grew
from
3,889
to
13,698
from
1920
to
1932.44
Analysts
of
this
era
cannot
generally
explain
why
the
decrease
in
crime
happened
after
1933,
but
the
end
of
Prohibition
is
certainly
a
conspicuous
factor.45
Crime
rates
remained
low
until
the
mid‐1960s,
which
is
another
conspicuous
time,
when
prohibitions
against
drugs
began
to
increase,
perhaps
in
response
to
the
increased
usage
of
returning
Viet
Nam
veterans.46
1.7
Section
Summary
In
this
section
we
have
discussed
some
of
the
general
features
of
prohibition
with
examples
referring
to
alcohol
Prohibition
in
the
early
20th
century.
We
saw
that
alcohol
consumption
did
decrease,
first
dramatically,
and
then
42
John
Stossel,
“Prohibition
Spawns
Drug
Violence,”
Creators
Syndicate
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]:
available
from
http://www.creators.com/opinion/john‐stossel/prohibition‐spawns‐drug‐ violence.html
43
Miron
and
Zwiebel,
“The
Economic
Case,”
180.
44
Thornton,
The
Economics
of
Prohibition,
123.
45
Thornton,
The
Economics
of
Prohibition,
124.
46
Thornton,
The
Economics
of
Prohibition,
125.
United
States
Drug
Policy
17
consumption
stabilized
at
about
60‐70%
of
pre‐Prohibition
levels.
As
we
have
also
seen,
prohibition
is
associated
with
many
negative
unforeseen
side‐ effects,
namely:
the
establishment
of
black
markets,
substitution,
political
corruption,
adulteration,
increased
potency,
increased
crime,
and
external
foreign
effects.
These
effects
are
not
exclusive
to
alcohol
Prohibition
in
the
United
States
in
the
early
20th
century;
they
are
effects
that
are
common
to
all
substance
prohibitions.
They
key
for
policy
makers
is
to
consider
whether
the
costs
of
enforcing
a
prohibition
outweigh
the
benefits,
or
if
the
effects
of
the
prohibition
reduce
costs
to
society.
Perhaps
a
quote
by
the
great
Austrian
Economist
Ludwig
von
Mises
on
the
subject
of
intervention
is
instructive:
We
are
exclusively
concerned
with
those
acts
of
interference
which
aim
at
forcing
the
entrepreneurs
and
capitalists
to
employ
the
factors
of
production
in
a
way
different
from
what
they
would
have
done
if
they
merely
obeyed
the
dictates
of
the
market.
In
doing
this,
we
do
not
raise
the
question
of
whether
such
interference
is
good
or
bad
from
any
preconceived
point
of
view.
We
merely
ask
whether
or
not
it
can
attain
those
ends
which
those
advocating
and
resorting
to
it
are
trying
to
attain.47
2.
Recent
History
of
the
War
on
Drugs
The
1970s
represent
a
time
in
the
U.S.
when
drug
policy
was
more
focused
on
treatment
rather
than
prevention
and
punishment,
but
also
a
time
when
the
federal
government
greatly
expanded
its
jurisdiction
over
all
drug
offenses
beginning
with
the
Comprehensive
Drug
Abuse
Prevention
and
Control
Act
of
47
Thornton,
The
Economics
of
Prohibition,
73.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
18
1970.48
This
law
created
the
drug
scheduling
system
that
divides
all
drugs
into
five
categories
based
on
their:
potential
for
abuse,
accepted
medical
use,
and
their
accepted
safety
under
medical
supervision.49
The
legal
foundation
for
the
federal
government’s
fight
against
drug
abuse,
the
Controlled
Substances
Act
of
1970,
was
also
included
within
this
act.50
Soldiers
came
home
from
Viet
Nam
addicted
to
various
drugs
including
marijuana,
opium
and
heroin
and
so
the
strategy
was
to
treat
these
soldiers
rather
than
to
punish
them:
It
was
at
this
time
that
the
U.S.
was
at
the
forefront
of
innovation
in
drug
policy
having
introduced
the
policy
of
using
methadone,
a
synthetic
opiate,
for
the
treatment
of
heroin
addicts.51
Between
1970
and
1975,
over
65%
of
the
U.S.
drug
budget
focused
on
prevention,
education
and
treatment;
over
the
next
five
years
this
proportion
shrank
to
43%;
and
in
1981
the
budget
for
demand‐side
policies
was
further
reduced.52
Since
that
time
the
U.S.
has
greatly
restricted
the
use
of
methadone.
Two
years
after
president
Nixon
first
declared
the
War
on
Drugs
in
1971
the
Drug
Enforcement
Administration
was
formed
and
from
then
on
it
would
have
the
major
responsibility
for
conducting
drug
seizures.53
Following
the
trend
of
increasing
federal
power
to
fight
the
drug
war,
the
Comprehensive
Drug
Abuse
Prevention
and
Control
Act
was
passed
in
1978,
which
allowed
for
the
seizure
of
assets
(money,
property
and
real
estate)
in
48
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
27.
49
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
27.
50
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
27.
51
Ethan
A.
Nadelmann,
“Commonsense
Drug
Policy,”
Foreign
Affairs
77,
no.
1
(1998):
117.
52
Anna
Celeste
Burke,
“Between
Entitlement
and
Control:
Dimensions
of
U.S.
Drug
Policy,”
The
Social
Service
Review
66,
no.
4
(1992):
573.
53
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
28.
United
States
Drug
Policy
19
cases
where
drug
industry
involvement
was
suspected.54
This
law
was
a
rather
striking
example
of
how
the
fundamentals
of
American
law
were
being
altered
to
facilitate
the
drug
war.
The
Fourth
Amendment
to
the
U.S.
Constitution
prohibits
unreasonable
search
and
seizure,
or
the
exercise
of
these
police
powers
without
probable
cause,
however,
now
there
is
a
drug
exception
to
this
longstanding
limitation
on
police
powers,
which
is
indicative
of
the
erosion
of
the
people’s
constitutional
rights.
In
addition,
this
policy
begs
the
question
of
how
one
is
to
organize
a
legal
defense
if
all
assets
have
been
seized
by
the
state:
This
policy
may
in
fact
mean
that
all
defendants
suspected
of
drug
industry
involvement
are
automatically
relegated
to
largely
incompetent
public
defenders
and
are
thus
incapable
of
mounting
a
successful
defense.
With
the
Comprehensive
Crime
Control
Act
of
1984,
the
federal
government
increased
its
ability
to
seize
assets,
to
invade
privacy
under
the
auspices
of
money
laundering
investigations,
to
lengthen
drug‐ related
prison
sentences
while
at
the
same
time
increasing
bail
rates.55
One
further
example
of
how
the
government
has
overturned
long‐standing
protections
of
citizen’s
rights
regards
the
principle
of
Posse
Comitatus,
which
until
1981
prevented
the
use
of
military
forces
for
domestic
police
duties.56
Since
1981
the
military
has
been
used
for
interdiction
of
drugs,
even
within
the
U.S.,
and
to
provide
training
to
local
police
forces.57
By
1979
drug
usage
had
exploded
in
relative
terms
reaching
all
time
usage
highs
when
25
million
people
indicated
that
they
had
used
illegal
drugs
54
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
28.
55
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
29.
56
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
29.
57
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
29.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
20
within
the
previous
month
according
statistics
compiled
by
the
ONDCP.58
The
political
reaction
to
this
phenomenon
was
a
movement
determined
to
get
tough
on
drugs,
and
all
throughout
the
1980s
government
involvement
increased
and
penalties
for
all
drug
related
offenses
stiffened.
By
the
end
of
the
decade
the
rate
of
drug
arrests
nearly
doubled
from
256
to
449
per
100,000,
and
greater
than
50%
of
all
federal
inmates
were
drug
offenders
by
1991.59
As
the
media
increasingly
reported
various
drug‐related
stories,
which
often
were
violent,
politicians
increasingly
demonized
drug
use,
and
actually
began
to
compete
with
each
other
regarding
which
party
would
be
toughest
on
crime.60
During
July
1986
alone
the
three
major
networks
ran
74
stories
about
drugs,
half
of
which
were
about
crack
cocaine,
which
provoked
the
most
public
concern
at
the
time;
this
is
perhaps
a
good
example
of
the
media
creating
a
moral
panic
that
is
soon
followed
by
strong
government
action.61
By
1986,
when
president
Ronald
Reagan
re‐declared
the
War
on
Drugs,
a
media
firestorm
erupted,
which
was
soon
followed
by
public
opinion
polls
that
listed
drugs
as
the
most
important
problem
facing
the
country,
rising
from
3%
in
1986
to
64%
in
1989.62
Also
during
this
period
Senator
Bob
Dole
introduced
a
bill
to
increase
the
penalties
for
possession
of
crack
cocaine
twenty‐fold,
the
Democrats
responded
by
demanding
a
fifty‐fold
58
Anonymous,
“Drug
Use
Trends,”
Office
of
National
Drug
Control
Policy
(October
2002
[cited
16
Jul.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.whitehousedrugpolicy.gov/publications/factsht/druguse/
59
Ellen
Benoit,
“Not
Just
a
Matter
of
Criminal
Justice:
States,
Institutions,
and
North
American
Drug
Policy,”
Sociological
Forum
18,
no.
2
(2003):
285.
60
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
13.
61
Schneider,
Racism,
Drug
Policy,
and
AIDS,
435.
62
Katherine
Beckett
“Setting
the
Public
Agenda:
“Street
Crime”
and
Drug
Use
in
American
Politics,”
Social
Problems
41,
no.
3
(1994):
425.
United
States
Drug
Policy
21
increase
in
the
penalty;
both
finally
settled
on
a
one‐hundred‐fold
increase
in
the
penalty
for
possession
of
crack.63
One
reaction
to
the
trend
of
increased
usage
was
the
passage
of
the
Anti‐Drug
Abuse
Act
of
1988,
which
had
the
specific
goals
of
reducing
illicit
drug
use,
manufacturing,
trafficking,
drug‐related
crime
and
violence,
and
drug‐related
health
consequences.64
The
major
provisions
of
the
Anti‐Drug
Abuse
Act
of
1988
consisted
of:
(1)
authorizing
additional
funds
for
law
enforcement
and
drug‐abuse
education
and
treatment
programs;
(2)
establishing
new
record‐keeping
controls
over
chemicals
used
in
the
manufacture
of
illegal
drugs;
(3)
establishing
penalties
for
diversion
of
such
precursor
chemicals
into
illegal‐drug
manufacture;
(4)
denying
certain
federal
benefits
to
drug
offenders;
(5)
prohibiting
awards
to
federal
contractors
who
fail
to
maintain
drug‐fee
workplaces;
(6)
imposing
the
death
penalty
on
drug
kingpins
for
certain
drug‐related
killings;
(7)
creating
a
cabinet‐level
position
of
federal
“drug
czar”
in
the
executive
office
of
the
President;
(8)
enhancing
civil
and
criminal
penalties
against
drug
users
(including
up
to
$10,000
in
civil
fines);
and,
overall,
(9)
strengthening
international
narcotics
control
programs.65
In
order
to
accomplish
these
objectives,
the
newly
created
position
of
“Drug
Czar”
was
to
head
the
new
Office
of
National
Drug
Control
Policy
(ONDCP),
which
now
directs
national
anti‐drug
efforts,
and
coordinates
the
various
agencies
on
the
federal,
state
and
local
levels.66
Interestingly,
since
the
creation
of
the
ONDCP
in
1988,
drug
usage
patterns
have
remained
stable
63
Schneider,
Racism,
Drug
Policy,
and
AIDS,
435.
64
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
3.
65
Raphael
Francis
Perl,
“Congress,
International
Narcotics
Policy,
and
the
Anti‐Drug
Abuse
Act
of
1988,”
Journal
of
Interamerican
Studies
and
World
Affairs
30,
no.
2/3
(1988):
34.
66
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
3.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
22
with
no
long‐term
increase
or
decrease
in
usage.67
Because
of
the
influence
of
the
ONDCP,
the
enormous
amount
of
money
that
is
annually
spent
on
the
drug
war,
and
the
effect
of
the
drug
war
on
the
liberty
and
security
of
the
total
population,
it
is
clear
that
the
effectiveness
of
the
ONDCP
must
be
evaluated
according
to
its
stated
goals.
In
the
evaluation
of
the
ONDCP
in
this
paper,
we
will
consider
the
following
stated
goals
of
that
organization:
reduction
of
illicit
drug
use,
manufacturing,
trafficking,
drug‐related
crime
and
violence,
and
drug‐related
health
consequences
among
other
things.
Upon
assuming
the
presidency
in
1989,
President
George
H.W.
Bush
redefined
U.S.
drug
war
strategy
within
the
contexts
of
both
domestic
and
foreign
policy.
One
of
the
flagship
goals
of
the
new
policy
was
to
reduce
the
quantity
of
illicit
substances
entering
the
U.S.
by
15%
within
2
years,
and
by
60%
within
10
years;
needless
to
say,
this
failed.68
The
strategy
to
complete
these
objectives
consisted
of
four
points:
(1)
provide
‐
for
the
first
time
‐
support
for
limited
economic
assistance
to
major
cocaine‐producing
countries;
(2)
concentrate
more
on
disrupting
the
activities
of
the
trafficking
organizations
[i.e.
on
seizing
processing
labs,
chemicals
and
assets]
and
less
on
disrupting
the
activities
of
farmers
[i.e.,
crop
eradication];
(3)
encourage
increased
levels
of
Andean
nation
military
involvement
in
counternarcotics
operations;
and
(4)
provide
for
enhanced
US
military
support
to
host
nation
counter‐narcotics
forces.
Coordination
of
US
international
drug
efforts
‐
among
Federal
agencies,
with
producer
and
transit
nations,
and
with
the
emerging
international
initiatives
of
other
consumer
nations
‐
also
receives
greater
policy
67
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
4.
68
Raphael
Francis
Perl,
“United
States
International
Drug
Policy:
Recent
Developments
and
Issues,”
Journal
of
Interamerican
Studies
and
World
Affairs
32,
no.
4
(1990):
123.
United
States
Drug
Policy
23
emphasis
under
the
strategy.69
Certainly
nobody
questioned
whether
president
Bush
considered
the
drug
war
to
be
an
international
issue
after
he
ordered
the
invasion
of
Panama
in
1989,
explicitly
conducted
due
to
drug
concerns.70
The
day
after
the
invasion
he
addressed
the
public:
Fellow
citizens,
last
night
I
ordered
U.S.
military
forces
to
Panama.
…
The
goals
of
the
United
States
have
been
to
safeguard
the
lives
of
Americans,
to
defend
democracy
in
Panama,
to
combat
drug
trafficking,
and
to
protect
the
integrity
of
the
Panama
Canal
Treaty.
Many
attempts
have
been
made
to
resolve
the
crisis
through
diplomacy
and
negotiations.
All
were
rejected
by
the
dictator
of
Panama,
General
Manuel
A.
Noriega,
an
indicted
drug
trafficker.71
Consistent
with
his
CIA
background,
Bush
sought
high
value
targets
that
would
disrupt
trafficking
operations,
which
would
be
selected
through
improved
intelligence
gathering
capabilities
at
all
governmental
levels
(local,
statewide,
national
and
international).72
The
Andean
Initiative,
also
implemented
during
this
period,
sought
to
enhance
the
capabilities
of
these
Andean
producer
countries
to
fight
against
traffickers
by
improving
local
economies
and
the
ability
of
these
countries
to
build
institutions.73
The
question
analysts
of
drug
policy
need
to
ask
themselves
is
how
reasonable
are
the
expectations
of
the
U.S.
regarding
other
country’s
domestic
attention
to
the
drug
issue?
69
Perl,
“United
States
International
Drug
Policy,”
124.
70
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
31.
71
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
31.
72
Perl,
“United
States
International
Drug
Policy,”
124.
73
Perl,
“United
States
International
Drug
Policy,”
124.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
24
2.1
Foreign
Issues
It
is
likely
that
other
countries
do
not
appreciate
the
persistence
of
U.S.
demands
in
this
area,
especially
when
they
conflict
with
historically
acceptable
local
uses
of
drugs,
like
chewing
the
coca
leaf
in
Bolivia,
for
example.
In
fact,
from
the
perspective
of
many
producer
countries,
the
best
thing
that
could
happen
would
be
the
international
legalization
of
illicit
drug
markets.
Even
the
current
Drug
Czar
admitted
as
much
when
he
stated
“Our
nation’s
demand
for
drugs
fuels
drug
production
and
trafficking,
as
well
as
violence
and
corruption,
within
other
nations.”74
Presently,
many
weak
Latin
American
governments
have
been
increasingly
strained
by
their
attempts
to
control
drug
traffickers
at
the
behest
of
the
U.S.
Beyond
the
instability
that
is
caused
by
these
governments
in
their
attempt
to
please
the
U.S.,
further
instability
is
caused
by
direct
U.S.
military
intervention,
as
it
has
been,
for
example,
in
Bolivia,
Panama,
and
Colombia.75
International
foreign
aid
supplied
to
these
countries
to
support
their
fight
against
the
traffickers
is
no
match
for
the
profits
these
traffickers
reap
from
supplying
the
vociferous
U.S.
appetite
for
these
substances.
Latin
American
governments
are
undermined
as
symbols
of
authority
and
justice
by
the
corruption
the
drug
war
brings
to
their
countries,
and
through
the
destruction
of
crops
that
their
citizens
depend
on
for
their
livelihoods.76
The
U.S.
directly
undermines
precarious
Latin
American
governments
when
it
directly
acts
against
traffickers
with
its
military.
In
the
74
Kerlikowske,
Gil.
“Domestic
Policy
Subcommittee”
75
Nadelmann,
“A
Bad
Export,”
83.
76
Nadelmann,
“A
Bad
Export,”
88.
United
States
Drug
Policy
25
1990s
the
U.S.
used
an
air
brigade
to
disrupt
traffic
between
Peru
and
Colombia,
a
producer
and
a
distributer
country
respectively,
through
the
use
of
airstrikes
against
suspicious
planes.77
These
strikes
greatly
increased
the
anger
and
resentment
felt
in
Latin
America
toward
the
U.S.,
but
they
were
not
stopped
until
the
strikes
accidentally
killed
American
missionaries.78
The
Andean
Initiative,
introduced
by
the
Bush
the
Elder’s
administration
in
1991,
sought
to
increase
assistance
to
the
governments
of
Bolivia,
Colombia,
and
Peru
by
attempting:
(1)
to
help
these
nations
strengthen
their
political/economic
conditions
and
institutional
capability
to
take
effective
action
against
the
trafficking
organizations;
(2)
to
increase
the
effectiveness
of
their
military
and
law
enforcement
establishments
against
the
cocaine
trade
by
supporting
efforts
(a)
to
isolate
major
coca‐growing
regions,
(b)
to
destroy
labs,
and
(c)
to
block
delivery
of
precursor
chemicals;
and
(3)
to
damage
drug‐trafficking
organizations
operating
in
these
countries
as
much
as
possible
by
directing
U.S.
assistance
to
support
measures
designed
to
seize
key
traffickers
and
their
assets.79
This
initiative
failed
to
achieve
its
objective
over
the
long
term,
most
likely
due
to
the
vast
profit
potential
that
exists
in
this
market.
In
addition
to
the
“carrot”
of
providing
aid
to
countries
designed
to
improve
their
ability
to
fight
trafficking,
the
U.S.
has
not
been
shy
about
employing
the
“stick”
approach
of
applying
sanctions
to
countries
that
do
not
acquiesce
to
U.S.
demands
in
this
area.80
77
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
33.
78
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
33.
79
Perl,
“United
States
International
Drug
Policy,”
124.
80
Perl,
“United
States
International
Drug
Policy,”
133.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
26
Farmers
in
these
poor
countries
simply
cannot
grow
another
crop
that
produces
a
similar
income.
Related
to
this
specific
point
is
the
fact
that
there
is
policy
incoherence
of
the
part
of
the
U.S.:
Available
agricultural
alternatives
to
growing
illicit
substances
are
further
reduced
by
the
U.S.
tariff
barriers
that
these
alternatives
are
subject
to.81
Attempts
to
encourage
farmers
to
grow
other
crops
through
crop
substitution
programs
have
failed
in
the
past,
due
in
large
part
to
the
profit
potential
of
the
drug
trade,
while
eradication
efforts
have
been
successful
in
destroying
crops
in
limited
areas
only
to
ensure
that
the
crops
are
planted
in
different
areas
with
no
discernable
effect
on
total
supply
or
price
levels.82
One
should
not
underestimate
the
effects
of
international
institution
building
on
the
ability
of
countries
to
creatively
solve
complex
problems.
More
than
180
countries
currently
adhere
to
UN
anti‐drug
conventions,
at
least
technically.83
Proponents
of
international
organizations
would
likely
characterize
this
as
a
success,
as
would
the
U.S.
due
to
the
nature
of
these
conventions,
but
some
countries,
like
Holland
and
Portugal,
have
sited
these
conventions
as
an
impediment
to
their
ability
to
adapt
their
policies
as
they
wish.84
Specifically,
the
1988
Convention
requires
signatories
to
participate
in
a
scheme
directed
against
international
money
laundering
and
to
establish
“the
possession,
purchase
or
cultivation
of
…
drugs
…
for
personal
consumption”
as
a
criminal
offense.85
The
UN,
therefore,
represents
a
serious
81
Perl,
“United
States
International
Drug
Policy,”
128.
82
Nadelmann,
Commonsense
Drug
Policy,
113.
83
Anonymous,
2008
World
Drug
Report,
21.
84
Anonymous,
2008
World
Drug
Report,
21.
85
Anonymous,
2008
World
Drug
Report,
206.
United
States
Drug
Policy
27
impediment
to
legalization
of
drugs
in
any
country,
a
fact
that
U.S.
policymakers
must
also
recognize.
2.2
Monetary
Costs
Profits
in
the
international
drug
trade
are
enormous
due
to
the
risk
premiums
that
are
factored
into
the
price
of
these
drugs
on
all
levels
of
the
distribution
chain.
Drug
war
proponents
argue
that
one
way
to
ultimately
decrease
usage
is
to
drive
up
the
price
of
these
goods
through
tough
enforcement,
but
data
on
drug
prices
do
not
necessarily
demonstrate
success
concerning
this
objective.
In
2001
the
U.S.
Coastguard
seized
21
tons
of
cocaine,
which
represented
a
$21
million
retail
value,
but
this
seizure
had
no
discernable
effect
on
the
street
price
of
the
drug.86
In
fact,
ample
evidence
suggests
that
the
whole
international
drug
trade
may
be
getting
more
efficient,
and
that
prohibition
actually
increases
the
profitability,
and
thus
the
incentives
for
traffickers:
During
the
period
between
1980
and
1990
the
street
price
of
both
heroin
and
cocaine
fell
by
half.87
This
is
certainly
a
failure
from
the
perspective
of
the
prohibitionists.
Even
so,
it
is
estimated
that
prices
for
illicit
drug
have
been
pushed
further
above
the
cost
of
production
than
during
alcohol
Prohibition,
most
likely
due
to
increased
enforcement.88
America
is
widely
believed
to
be
the
world’s
most
valuable
drug
market
with
an
estimated
annual
retail
value
in
excess
of
$60
billion,
a
value
that
is
likely
inflated
by
the
effects
of
prohibition.89
In
other
words,
the
86
Anonymous,
The
Case
for
Legalization,
18.
87
Anonymous,
The
Case
for
Legalization,
10.
88
Miron
and
Zwiebel,
“Alcohol
Consumption,”
246.
89
Anonymous,
The
Case
for
Legalization,
4.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
28
American
market
represents
20%
of
the
value
of
the
entire
world
drug
market,
which
is
valued
at
$300
billion.90
In
addition
to
the
price
effects
associated
with
prohibition,
the
opportunity
costs
of
fighting
the
drug
war
are
large.
The
federal
drug
control
budget
has
ballooned
from
$1
billion
in
1980
to
$16
billion
in
1997,
which
does
not
include
the
state
and
local
budgets
that
most
certainly
match
or
exceed
that
number.91
For
reasons
to
be
discussed
later,
it
is
currently
difficult
to
estimate
the
present
annual
drug
control
budget.
According
to
Jeffrey
Miron,
a
Harvard
economist,
marijuana
legalization
could
potentially
save
$7.7
billion,
and
drugs,
if
taxed,
could
raise
an
additional
$6
billion
if
they
were
taxed
like
tobacco
and
liquor.92
In
times
of
financial
crisis,
when
state
and
federal
officials
must
tighten
their
budgetary
belts,
raising
that
much
money
is
becoming
an
increasingly
attractive
proposition.
2.3
Corruption
As
mentioned
as
a
general
property
of
substance
prohibition
in
the
last
section,
the
level
of
corruption
is
a
function
of
the
price
of
the
prohibited
substance
or
the
profit
potential
of
the
substance’s
market.
As
enforcement
has
increased
more
corruption
has
been
detected
in
the
U.S.:
between
1970
and
1988
federal
convictions
for
corruption
have
increased
from
44
to
1067
per
year.93
Some
new
law
enforcement
trends
have
also
emerged
since
the
90
Perl,
“United
States
International
Drug
Policy,”
127.
91
Nadelmann,
Commonsense
Drug
Policy,
112.
92
David
Crary,
“Momentum
Builds
for
Broad
Debate
on
Legalizing
Pot,”
The
Associated
Press
(Jun.
15
2009
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.google.com/hostednews/ap/article/ALeqM5i_7aIzdypWz2A‐ dtVHeJ8VZ7vLFAD98R92S80
93
Thornton,
The
Economics
of
Prohibition,
127.
United
States
Drug
Policy
29
strengthening
of
enforcement
began
in
the
early
1980s.
One
of
theses
trends
is
referred
to
as
“testalying”:
this
is
when
an
officer
lies
on
the
witness
stand
in
order
to
ensure
a
conviction,
for
noble
reasons,
for
instance
to
put
legitimate
criminals
behind
bars,
or
for
not
so
noble
reasons,
for
instance
lying
to
put
one
group
of
criminals
behind
bars
for
the
purpose
of
protecting
another
group
that
pays
the
officer
for
the
services.94
The
perverse
incentives
of
the
current
legal
framework,
which
allow
police
departments
to
retain
the
assets
seized
in
drug
busts,
certainly
lead
to
corruption
and
the
further
militarization
of
domestic
police
forces;
even
in
small
towns
across
the
country
one
can
find
various
paramilitary
or
tactical
SWAT
teams.95
Recently
a
mayor
from
Berwyn
Heights,
Maryland
filed
a
civil
rights
lawsuit
related
to
a
raid
on
his
house
in
2008,
when
the
SWAT
team
shot
his
two
dogs
and
tied
him
and
his
mother‐in‐law
to
chairs
and
questioned
them
for
over
two
hours
about
a
package
of
marijuana
that
was
delivered
to
his
house
a
part
of
a
drug
distribution
scheme
that
sends
packages
to
houses
to
be
retrieved
before
the
homeowners
return.96
Mayor
Cheye
Calvo
said
after
the
event
“"In
some
ways,
we
were
lucky.
We
had
the
support
of
our
community,
who
knew
we
weren't
drug
dealers.
It
didn't
take
long
for
me
to
realize
that
many
people
this
kind
of
thing
happens
to
don't
have
that
kind
of
support."97
Clearly
if
this
type
of
criminal
behavior
by
the
police
can
target
a
mayor,
anyone
could
be
victimized
in
the
same
way.
94
Anonymous,
The
Case
for
Legalization,
20.
95
Anonymous,
The
Case
for
Legalization,
21.
96
Radley
Balko,
“SWAT
Gone
Wild
in
Maryland,”
Reason
Online
(Jul.
13,
2009
[cited
16
Jul.
2009]):
available
at
http://www.reason.com/news/show/134734.html
97
Balko,
SWAT
Gone
Wild
in
Maryland
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
30
2.4
Social
Class
Effects
Poor
citizens
are
most
likely
to
become
involved
in
the
drug
industry
because
of
the
income
disparity
that
exists
between
the
jobs
that
they
can
lawfully
acquire
and
jobs
as
low‐level
drug
runners.
In
Washington
DC,
during
the
height
of
the
crack
cocaine
epidemic
in
the
1980s,
illicit
employment
in
the
drug
industry
paid
approximately
$30
per
hour,
while
legal
employment
opportunities
pad
an
average
of
$7
per
hour.98
The
situation
of
the
poor
was
further
exacerbated
by
the
focus
of
the
Reagan
administration
on
street
crime,
the
most
important
part
of
which
was
drug
dealing,
and
which
focuses
disproportionately
on
poorer
citizens
and
minorities.99
Besides
being
more
likely
to
participate
in
illicit
markets,
the
urban
poor
also
find
themselves
the
target
of
the
highest
concentration
of
police
presence;
whether
this
is
due
to
race
or
class
discrimination,
or
due
to
the
fact
that
a
higher
proportion
of
illegal
activities
take
place
there,
is
unknown.100
African
Americans
represent
12%
of
the
total
population,
but
account
for
52%
of
all
drug
arrests;
this
means
that
African
Americans
are
four
times
as
likely
as
White
Americans
to
be
arrested.101
This
trend
is
also
true
for
young
African
Americans;
in
1992
the
proportion
of
juvenile
cases
was
higher
for
African
American
than
for
other
groups,
and
nearly
five
times
as
many
Black
youths
were
taken
to
court
for
drug‐related
crimes.102
Current
U.S.
policy
continues
to
punish
these
citizens
after
they
are
released
from
prison
by
denying
them
Supplemental
98
Anonymous,
The
Case
for
Legalization,
11.
99
Beckett,
“Setting
the
Public
Agenda”,
427.
100
Benoit,
“Not
Just
a
Matter”,
272.
101
Janice
Joseph
and
Patricia
G.
Pearson,
“Black
Youths
and
Illegal
Drugs,”
Journal
of
Black
Studies
32,
no.
4
(2002):
431.
102
Joseph
and
Pearson,
Black
Youths
and
Illegal
Drugs,
425.
United
States
Drug
Policy
31
Security
Income,
or
welfare,
and
by
preventing
them
from
applying
for
federal
student
aid,
which
all
but
destroys
the
chances
of
a
rehabilitated
offender
to
achieve
long‐term
success.103
Racial
differences
in
drug
and
alcohol
use
disappear
as
income
increases;
however,
poor
African
Americans
are
more
likely
to
use
certain
classes
of
drugs
like
intravenous
heroin
and
crack
cocaine,
for
example.104
The
focus
of
many
police
departments
on
crack
cocaine
disproportionately
affects
African
Americans
by
focusing
on
drugs
that
they
are
more
likely
to
consume.
Some
evidence
even
suggests
a
connection
between
increased
enforcement
and
increased
rates
of
HIV/AIDS,
especially
among
members
of
minority
populations.
Minority
populations
are
likely
to
live
in
high‐density
areas
surrounded
mostly
by
other
minority
citizens.
Because
there
already
is
a
police
bias
against
areas
dominated
by
minorities
because
of
the
increased
crime
rates
in
those
areas,
police
presence
has
been
connected
to
higher
HIV
transmission
rates.105
Because
of
the
high
concentration
of
police
and
laws
forbidding
the
possession
of
drug
paraphernalia,
it
is
highly
risky
to
possess
sterile
needles
in
minority
neighborhoods.106
A
study
conducted
in
Seattle
concluded
that
three
factors
contributed
to
the
racial
disparity
in
enforcement
arrests;
the
first
was
a
focus
on
crack
cocaine;
the
second
was
the
lack
of
access
to
private
space
among
minority
users;
and
the
third
was
103
Benoit,
“Not
Just
a
Matter”,
271.
104
Kellie
E.
M.
Barr,
Michael
P.
Farrell,
Grace
M.
Barnes,
John
W.
Welte,
“Race,
Class,
and
Gender
Differences
in
Substance
Abuse:
Evidence
of
Middle‐Class/Underclass
Polarization
Among
Blacks,”
Social
Problems
40,
no.
3
(1993):
321.
105
Schneider,
Racism,
Drug
Policy,
and
AIDS,
432.
106
Schneider,
Racism,
Drug
Policy,
and
AIDS,
432.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
32
the
focus
on
outdoor
drug
use
and
distribution.107
It
is
unclear
how
the
conclusions
of
the
Seattle
study
apply
to
the
rest
of
the
country,
or
the
reasons
for
the
adoption
of
this
strategy,
but
it
is
clear
that,
at
least
in
Seattle,
White
users
and
distributors
have
an
advantage
because
of
the
strategy.
Arrest
avoidance
strategies
include
the
borrowing
of
syringes
upon
purchase
of
drugs
for
immediate
use,
and
the
underground
shooting
gallery,
which
are
the
riskiest
regarding
the
spread
of
HIV
due
to
the
sharing
of
needles
and
the
exchange
of
sex
for
drugs
that
happens
there.108
Due
to
these
factors,
as
well
as
the
increased
chances
of
contracting
HIV
in
prison,
minority
populations
are
more
likely
than
Whites
to
contract
the
disease
in
these
ways,
and
for
these
reasons.
Since
the
crack
trade
has
stabilized
since
the
1980s,
associated
homicides
have
fallen,
but
health
risks
to
minority
populations
in
inner
cities
have
increased.
This
is
due
to
the
substitution
effect
mentioned
in
the
previous
section;
rather
than
consume
smokable
crack,
which
carries
severe
penalties,
new
trends
suggest
that
consumers
in
these
areas
are
injecting
powdered
cocaine,
which
carries
even
higher
risks
of
HIV
contraction
than
heroin
because
of
the
greater
frequency
of
associated
injections.
Estimates
in
1990,
considering
drug‐related
murders,
drug‐ related
AIDS
deaths,
and
deaths
caused
by
poisoned
or
adulterated
drugs,
found
8250
annual
drug
prohibition
related
deaths
in
the
U.S.
alone.109
107
Katherine
Beckett,
Kris
Nyrop,
Lori
Pfingst,
Melissa
Bowen,
“Drug
Use,
Drug
Possession
Arrests,
and
the
Question
of
Race:
Lessons
from
Seattle,”
Social
Problems
52,
no.
3
(2005):
434.
108
Schneider,
Racism,
Drug
Policy,
and
AIDS,
432.
109
Konrad,
Drug
Policy
and
Federalism,
57.
United
States
Drug
Policy
33
2.5
Imprisonment
Mandatory
minimum
sentences
and
a
strict
enforcement
policy
in
the
U.S.
have
contributed
to
a
rapid
expansion
of
the
prison
population
in
the
U.S.
The
effect
of
mandatory
minimum
sentences
is
disproportionate
in
that,
since
their
establishment
in
the
1986
Anti‐Drug
Abuse
Act,
minorities
are
more
likely
to
receive
the
mandatory
minimums
than
Whites
by
a
margin
of
21%
for
Blacks
and
28%
for
Hispanics.110
Furthermore,
Blacks
and
Hispanics
are
more
likely
to
be
sent
to
state
or
federal
prisons,
while
Whites
are
more
likely
to
be
sent
to
county
prisons.111
Roughly
25%
of
all
prisoners
committed
drug‐related
crimes,
most
of
which
were
non‐violent
crimes,
and,
as
senator
Jim
Webb
recently
averred,
the
U.S.,
with
5%
of
the
world
population,
has
25%
of
the
world’s
prisoners,
which
costs
$68
billion
annually.112
47.5%
of
all
drug
arrests
are
for
marijuana
related
crimes,
which
dramatically
contributes
to
the
$150
billion
annual
cost
of
courts
and
policing.113
One
unforeseen
consequence
of
mandatory
minimum
sentencing
laws
has
been
an
increased
focus
on
low‐level
street
dealers
at
the
expense
of
investigating
upper
levels
of
the
drug
trade.114
Though
this
is
not
necessarily
a
racially
motivated
strategy,
one
can
certainly
see
how
this
would
disproportionately
affect
Blacks,
while
White
suburban
distributors
are
able
110
Schneider,
Racism,
Drug
Policy,
and
AIDS,
438.
111
Schneider,
Racism,
Drug
Policy,
and
AIDS,
438.
112
Joe
Klein,
“Why
Legalizing
Marijuana
Makes
Sense,”
Time
Magazine
(Apr.
2,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.time.com/time/nation/article/0,8599,1889021,00.html?iid=digg_share
113
Klein,
Why
Legalizing
Marijuana
Makes
Sense
114
Schneider,
Racism,
Drug
Policy,
and
AIDS,
440.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
34
to
avoid
detection.115
In
addition,
the
U.S.
has
underutilized
one
policy
option
with
proven
effectiveness:
the
drug
courts.
While
it
is
unfortunate
that
many
addicts
who
need
treatment
are
unable
to
get
it
unless
they
arrested,
the
recidivism
rate
for
those
who
receive
treatment
through
drug
courts
is
much
lower
at
17%
than
the
recidivism
rate
for
drug‐offenders
who
receive
no
treatment
at
60%.116
This
represents
a
significant
cost
savings
and
a
dramatic
usage
reduction,
and
thus
should
be
considered
in
any
serious
discussion
of
drug
policy
options.
Even
so,
according
to
Gil
Kerlikowske,
current
Drug
Czar,
of
the
20
million
people
diagnosed
with
substance
dependence
or
abuse
only
10%
received
treatment
for
the
disorder.117
With
the
high
costs
or
imprisonment
and
the
loss
of
tax
revenue
and
productivity
incurred
by
keeping
able‐bodied
individuals
out
of
the
work
force,
the
treatment
alternative
would
likely
benefit
offenders
and
taxpayers
alike.
2.6
Analysis
of
the
Effectiveness
of
the
ONDCP
One
of
the
stated
goals
of
the
ONDCP
is
to
ameliorate
the
health
consequences
of
drug
use.
It
is
difficult
to
discuss
the
positive
strides
the
U.S.
has
made
in
this
area
because,
even
though
harm
reduction
is
the
focal
point
of
the
drug
policies
of
most
countries
in
the
developed
world,
the
U.S.
has,
most
likely
for
domestic
political
reasons,
rejected
this
approach,
and
has
domestically
underfunded
associated
programs.
Not
only
has
the
U.S.
rejected
harm
reduction,
but
it
has
also
actively
attempted
to
affect
the
international
115
Schneider,
Racism,
Drug
Policy,
and
AIDS,
440.
116
Jim
Acosta
and
Kristi
Keck,
“White
House
Tries
to
Combat
Drug
Demand
with
Rehab,”
CNN
(Apr.
18,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://edition.cnn.com/2009/POLITICS/04/18/obama.drug.war/index.html
117
Kerlikowske,
Gil.
“Domestic
Policy
Subcommittee”
United
States
Drug
Policy
35
credibility
of
harm
reduction
by
blocking
resolutions
supporting
harm
reduction,
by
suppressing
scientific
studies
that
have
had
positive
findings
supporting
harm
reduction,
and
by
silencing
critics
of
official
U.S.
drug
policy.118
The
World
Health
Organization
(WHO)
conducted
a
wide‐ranging
study
on
the
global
usage
of
cocaine,
and
in
March
1995
they
released
a
summary
document
stating
their
results.119
This
report
was
highly
critical
of
U.S.
policies,
suggesting
that
interdiction
and
usage
prevention
strategies
had
failed,
and
that
harm
reduction
policies
were
more
likely
to
achieve
success.120
Due
to
what
were
considered
by
U.S.
policymakers
to
be
outrageous
and
dangerous
conclusions,
the
U.S.
representative
to
the
WHO
threatened
to
completely
withdraw
all
funding
for
the
organization
unless
the
WHO
suppressed
the
report,
which
has
yet
to
be
officially
published.121
Furthermore,
since
its
creation
in
1988,
the
ONDCP
has
never
appointed
a
physician,
or
health
care
professional
of
any
kind,
to
the
top
“Drug
Czar”
position
indicating
that
the
harm
reduction
approach
and
treatment
in
general
are
considered
to
be
extraneous
concerns.122
This
is
not
the
behavior
of
an
actor
that
intends
to
use
a
research‐based
strategy
to
decrease
usage
and
mitigate
the
negative
externalities
associated
with
drug
use.
The
ONDCP
is
not
an
independent
governmental
body;
it
is
part
of
the
executive
branch,
which
subjects
it
to
the
pressures
associated
with
complying
with
a
president’s
agenda.
Beyond
this
executive
influence
in
the
118
Nadelmann,
Commonsense
Drug
Policy,
124.
119
Ben
Goldacre,
“Cocaine
Study
That
Got
Up
the
Nose
of
the
US,”
The
Guardian
(Jun.
13
2009
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.guardian.co.uk/commentisfree/2009/jun/13/bad‐science‐cocaine‐study
120
Goldacre,
“Cocaine
Study”
121
Goldacre,
“Cocaine
Study”
122
Nadelmann,
Commonsense
Drug
Policy,
111.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
36
ONDCP,
the
organization
is
subject
to
all
of
the
features
common
to
bureaucracies,
namely
the
desire
to
expand,
the
tendency
to
define
success
in
terms
of
budget
increases,
and
the
struggle
to
maintain
and
expand
its
bureaucratic
turf.
In
order
to
facilitate
these
objectives
the
ONDCP
engages
in
claims
making,
attempts
to
cause
moral
panic,
and
dishonestly
uses
statistics
to
support
its
policy
positions
and
increase
its
strength.
The
policy
objectives
of
the
ONDCP
have
been
fluid
over
the
years,
which
may
explain
some
of
the
ineffectiveness
of
U.S.
drug
policy.
For
example,
the
2000
ONDCP
Strategy
states
“the
1996
Strategy
established
five
goals
and
thirty‐two
supporting
objectives
as
the
basis
for
a
coherent,
long‐ term
national
effort.
These
goals
remain
the
heart
of
the
1999
Strategy
and
will
guide
federal
drug
control
agencies
over
the
next
five
years.”123
However,
these
goals
were
subsequently
omitted
from
the
following
ONDCP
Strategies,
which
may
be
indicative
of
the
fact
that
policymakers
have
yet
to
reach
a
consensus
on
the
overall
goals
of
U.S.
drug
policy.124
The
first
step
to
creating
a
lasting
strategy
that
can
have
success
over
time
is
to
have
clear
objective
so
that
policies
can
be
measured
according
to
the
appropriate
metrics.
It
is
questionable
whether
or
not
this
is
possible
while
the
ONDCP
remains
a
part
of
the
executive
branch,
and
thus
subject
to
political
pressure.
The
ONDCP
has
further
confounded
evaluation
of
the
effectiveness
by
offering
misleading
statistics,
and
by
deliberately
underestimating
the
financial
costs
of
the
drug
war.
The
first
way
it
has
done
this
is
by
omitting
123
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
38
124
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
38
United
States
Drug
Policy
37
expenses
incurred
by
state,
city
and
county
police
forces
from
its
budget
statement.
This
is
inappropriate
because
all
local
and
state
police
force
have
drug
budgets,
and
by
omitting
these
costs
the
ONDCP
may
be
underestimating
costs
by
as
much
as
half
in
conjunction
with
the
following
point.125
Since
2003,
the
ONDCP
has
also
omitted
from
its
budget
all
expenses
that
are
incurred
that
do
not
relate
to
drug
policy
judgments,
which
means
in
practice
that
money
spent
on
arrests,
convictions,
and
corrections
are
not
included
in
its
budgetary
calculations.126
In
this
way,
ONDCP
policy
obscures
the
true
costs
associated
with
the
war
on
drugs,
and
confounds
analysts,
using
cost
benefit
analysis,
attempting
to
honestly
consider
the
effectiveness
of
the
policy.
In
addition
to
the
aforementioned
effects,
the
policy,
by
decreasing
total
drug
war
costs,
increases
the
proportion
of
the
drug
war
budget
that
is
apportioned
for
treatment.127
To
have
an
effective
and
honest
evaluation
of
current
policies
these
practices
must
be
eliminated.
2.7
Section
Summary
This
section
provided
an
overview
of
the
conditions
in
the
United
States
over
the
last
30
year
and
discussed
a
number
of
problems
including:
foreign
externalities,
financial
implications,
corruption,
social
effects
and
the
inadequacy
of
the
ONDCP.
These
are
challenging
problems,
and
they
certainly
require
policy
entrepreneurialism
to
solve.
These
problems,
however,
will
never
be
solved
without
considering
options
that
have
been
taboo
in
the
United
States
for
the
last
30
years.
As
we
will
see
in
section
4,
President
125
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
41
126
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
42
127
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
43
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
38
Obama
seems
much
more
receptive
to
the
idea
of
drug
policy
reform
at
a
time
when
public
opinion
is
increasingly
in
favor
of
it.
These
are
important
characteristics
that
will
increase
the
likelihood
of
a
successful
reform,
which,
as
has
been
discussed,
is
necessary.
3.
Harm
Reduction
Successes
in
Foreign
Countries
As
we
have
seen
so
far,
the
strategy
of
the
United
States
relies
almost
exclusively
on
enforcement,
which
is
a
supply‐side
policy.
Other
countries
have
had
success
focusing
on
harm
reduction,
or
the
demand‐side
policies.
Since
the
early
1980s
the
United
States
has
been
reluctant
to
take
harm
reduction
strategies
seriously
with
some
deleterious
effects,
and
not
much
success,
even
regarding
the
goals
that
should
be
easiest
to
accomplish,
like
increasing
the
price
of
drugs.
This
section
is
devoted
to
examining
the
specific
policies
of
other
countries,
mainly
Holland
and
Portugal,
which
have
approached
the
drug
problem
from
the
harm
reduction
perspective.
Some
drug
policy
analysts
have
criticized
the
relevance
of
country
case
studies
on
the
grounds
that
individual
countries’
cultures
and
treaty
obligations
preclude
effective
comparison,
however,
this
author
believes
that
these
studies
are
relevant
because
they
provide
possible
guidance
in
constructing
an
alternative
framework
in
the
United
States,
and
they
support
harm
reduction
as
an
effective
alternative
to
enforcement.
Before
beginning
with
the
case
studies,
we
should
briefly
describe
one
key
difference
between
the
approaches
of
most
Western
countries
and
the
United
States:
methadone
maintenance
treatment.
While
the
United
States
United
States
Drug
Policy
39
pioneered
the
use
of
methadone
to
treat
heroin
addiction,
this
practice
has
decreased
in
popularity
and
restrictions
have
increased
since
the
practice’s
development.
Presently
the
use
of
methadone
in
the
U.S.
is
restricted
to
a
very
small
group
of
addicts
whose
goal
is
to
quit.
While
methadone
treatment
can
be
used
to
achieve
this
objective,
many
other
Western
countries
use
methadone
to
maintain
addicts,
which
means
they
take
methadone
for
long
periods
to
prevent
the
onset
of
withdrawal
so
they
can
focus
on
improving
other
aspects
of
their
lives.
Some
examples
of
countries
that
do
this
are
Australia,
New
Zealand,
Canada,
Germany,
Holland,
and
Switzerland
to
name
a
few.128
In
Switzerland
a
trial
was
conducted
to
see
what
the
effects
of
prescribing
methadone,
heroin
and
morphine
to
addicts
were
on
crime
rates
and
disease.129
The
results
of
the
study
were
twofold:
first,
it
became
clear
that
addicts
preferred
heroin
to
methadone
or
morphine;
and
second,
criminal
offenses
and
the
total
number
of
offenders
fell
by
60%,
and
the
percentage
of
the
income
derived
from
crime
of
people
enrolled
in
the
trial
fell
from
69%
to
10%.130
In
addition,
the
use
of
illegal
heroin
and
cocaine
among
the
participants
fell,
and
stable
employment
rose
from
14
to
32
percent.131
Finally,
the
study
concluded
with
a
cost‐benefit
analysis
that
estimated
a
net
benefit
of
$30
per
patient
per
day
resulting
largely
from
the
associated
reduction
in
crime
rates.132
These
findings
are
both
interesting
and
relevant
to
the
United
States
because
of
the
high
crime
rates
associated
128
Nadelmann,
Commonsense
Drug
Policy,
118.
129
Nadelmann,
Commonsense
Drug
Policy,
120.
130
Nadelmann,
Commonsense
Drug
Policy,
120.
131
Nadelmann,
Commonsense
Drug
Policy,
120.
132
Nadelmann,
Commonsense
Drug
Policy,
120.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
40
with
hard‐drug
use
and
the
necessity
to
cut
costs,
especially
during
times
of
economic
depression,
which
the
country
is
now
experiencing.
3.1
The
Case
of
Holland
The
basis
of
Dutch
drug
policy
is
pragmatism;
the
policy
aims
at
normalizing
deviant
social
behaviors
in
favor
of
deterring
them.133
Illegal
drug
use
in
Holland
is
viewed
as
a
limited
and
manageable
problem,
which
is
best
dealt
with
in
a
way
that
does
not
stigmatize
users
and
reduces
the
overall
harm
to
all
social
groups,
even
users
themselves.
Cannabis
(marijuana
and
hashish)
has
been
de
facto
decriminalized
since
the
1970s,
and,
according
to
the
Dutch
drug‐scheduling
scheme,
cannabis
is
considered
to
be
a
schedule‐2
drug,
which
means
that
it
is
not
a
serious
health
threat.134
Users
of
cannabis
have
little
to
fear
in
Holland,
but
schedule
1
drugs,
or
drugs
with
unacceptable
risk,
are
still
illegal,
and
can
be
the
cause
of
criminal
sanctions.
What
this
means
in
practice
is
that
cannabis
consumers
are
easily
able
to
acquire
cannabis
at
“coffeeshops”,
where
the
product
strength
is
reliably
constant,
and
no
other
drugs
are
permitted
to
be
sold.135
This
has
had
the
effect
of
separating
soft‐
and
hard‐drug
dealers
in
a
way
that
reduces
public
contact
with
suppliers
of
hard‐drugs.
Trafficking
penalties
in
Holland
are
similar
to
penalties
in
other
Western
countries,
and
are
likely
to
remain
so
due
to
UN
treaty
obligations.136
The
question
with
the
most
relevance
for
American
drug
policy
analysts
is
how
has
de
facto
decriminalization
of
cannabis
affected
usage
rates
in
133
Ed
Leuw,
“Drugs
and
Drug
Policy
in
the
Netherlands,”
Crime
and
Justice
14,
no.
47
(1991):
230.
134
Leuw,
Drugs
and
Drug
Policy
in
the
Netherlands,
231.
135
Larry
Collins,
“Holland’s
Half‐Baked
Drug
Experiment,”
Foreign
Affairs
78,
no.
3
(1999):
83.
136
Leuw,
Drugs
and
Drug
Policy
in
the
Netherlands,
232.
United
States
Drug
Policy
41
Holland?
In
a
survey
conducted
in
1989
considering
the
usage
rates
of
Holland
as
compared
with
Norway,
Sweden
and
the
United
States
over
the
previous
20
year
period
concluded
the
following:
The
results
of
the
analysis
show
that
the
prevalence
of
[Dutch]
cannabis
use
since
1970
decreased,
whereas
the
policy
because
more
tolerant.
Since
1979
a
slight
increase
in
the
use
of
cannabis
can
be
observed.
A
comparison
with
data
from
countries
with
a
more
restrictive
policy
reveals
that
the
use
of
cannabis
in
the
Netherlands
is
on
the
same
level
as
in
Sweden
and
Norway,
but
far
lower
than
in
the
U.S.
However,
the
downward
trend
in
these
countries
since
1984
did
not
occur
in
the
Netherlands.137
The
era
of
tolerance
in
Holland
was
ushered
in
by
the
Hulsman
Committee,
which
maintained
that
pluralism
requires
that
norms
and
values
of
minority
subcultures
should
not
be
marginalized
by
popular
opinion.138
The
central
idea
is
that
state
policies
that
forbid
activities
that
affect
only
the
individual
are
inappropriate,
and
should
be
resisted
regardless
of
majority
opinion.139
The
result
of
this
commission
was
a
new
Dutch
strategy
with
the
following
characteristics:
“the
prevention
and
amelioration
of
social
and
individual
risks
caused
by
the
use
of
drugs;
a
rational
relation
between
those
risks
and
policy‐measures;
a
differentiation
of
policy‐measures
which
take
into
account
the
risks
of
legal
recreational
and
medical
drugs;
a
priority
of
repressive
measures
against
[other
than
cannabis]
drug
trafficking;
the
137
Leuw,
Drugs
and
Drug
Policy
in
the
Netherlands,
237.
138
Leuw,
Drugs
and
Drug
Policy
in
the
Netherlands,
244.
139
Leuw,
Drugs
and
Drug
Policy
in
the
Netherlands,
244.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
42
inadequacy
of
criminal
law
with
regard
to
any
other
aspect
of
the
drugs
problem.”140
To
be
sure,
there
are
some
negative
aspects
of
the
Dutch
model
as
well.
Dutch
decriminalization
has
lead
to
some
negative
externalities
for
the
neighboring
countries
of
the
Netherlands.
Holland
is
considered
by
many
to
be
the
“drug
capital
of
Western
Europe”,
even
though,
as
we
shall
see,
it
does
not
have
the
most
liberal
drug
policies
in
Western
Europe.141
Neighboring
counties
estimate
that
many
drugs,
especially
synthetic
drugs
like
ecstasy
(MDMA)
and
amphetamines,
originate
from
Holland
and
are
then
shipped
to
its
neighbors
by
traffickers.142
According
to
French
estimates,
in
1997,
98%
of
amphetamines
and
74%
of
ecstasy
tablets
originated
in
Holland.143
Also,
contrary
to
the
general
principles
of
prohibition
that
were
stated
in
the
first
section,
potency
levels
of
cannabis
have
steadily
increased
in
Holland,
which
has
some
concerned
about
the
health
risks
of
this
more
potent
variety
of
cannabis
called
Nederwiet.144
These
consequences
certainly
seem
to
indicate
a
failure
of
some
aspects
of
the
Dutch
decriminalization,
and
some
ascribe
these
failures
to
the
policy
itself
rather
than
considering
possible
alternative
reasons.
It
is
clear
that
Dutch
policies
affect
neighboring
countries,
but
so
do
neighboring
countries’
policies
affect
the
Dutch.
In
fact,
should
a
similar
policy
be
adopted
by
all
of
Holland’s
neighbors,
it
would
be
unnecessary
to
export
drugs
to
neighboring
countries,
unless
Holland
possessed
a
comparative
advantage
in
the
production
of
these
goods.
The
increasing
140
Leuw,
Drugs
and
Drug
Policy
in
the
Netherlands,
251.
141
Collins,
Holland’s
HalfBaked
Drug
Experiment,
83.
142
Collins,
Holland’s
HalfBaked
Drug
Experiment,
84.
143
Collins,
Holland’s
HalfBaked
Drug
Experiment,
84.
144
Collins,
Holland’s
HalfBaked
Drug
Experiment,
87.
United
States
Drug
Policy
43
potency
of
cannabis
produced
in
Holland
is
also
subject
to
external
pressure
of
neighboring
countries.
Due
to
the
prohibitions
that
still
exist
in
those
countries,
Dutch
cannabis
potency
may
have
increased
because
about
65
out
of
100
tons
of
cannabis
produced
in
Holland
is
exported
annually.145
The
increase
therefore,
could
be
due
to
the
continued
prohibition
in
neighboring
countries
that
have
markets
larger
than
the
Dutch
domestic
market,
which
would
be
consistent
with
the
previous
analysis
of
the
effects
of
prohibition.
The
Dutch
drug
market
is
characterized
as
peaceful
in
comparison
to
the
market
in
the
United
States,
though
firearm
use
is
occasional
at
the
top
levels.146
Nowadays
the
policy
is
non‐controversial
and
the
linkage
between
soft‐
and
hard‐drug
trafficking
has
been
broken.147
The
positive
effects
on
youth
drug
use
in
Holland
are
also
instructive:
15‐29
year
olds
smoke
50%
less
cannabis
than
American
youth
after
three
decades
of
decriminalization,
and
because
cannabis
distributors
no
longer
additionally
sell
heroin,
less
Dutch
youths
experiment
with
heroin.148
Between
the
ages
of
12‐15,
only
7.2%
of
Dutch
adolescents
report
having
tried
cannabis,
while
in
the
United
States
13.5%
reported
the
same,
however
far
fewer
Dutch
adolescents
report
having
used
hard‐drugs
than
their
American
counterparts.149
A
change
in
marijuana
policy
in
the
U.S.
could
result
in
a
great
increase
in
resources
because
marijuana
arrests
account
for
the
majority
of
all
drug
arrests,
as
well
145
Collins,
Holland’s
HalfBaked
Drug
Experiment,
89.
146
Leuw,
Drugs
and
Drug
Policy
in
the
Netherlands,
240.
147
Leuw,
Drugs
and
Drug
Policy
in
the
Netherlands,
256.
148
Frosty
Wooldridge,
“Marijuana
Prohibition
and
Public
Safety,”
The
Examiner
(Mar.
2,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.examiner.com/x‐3515‐Denver‐Political‐ Issues‐Examiner~y2009m3d2‐Marijuana‐prohibition‐and‐public‐safety
149
Nadelmann,
Commonsense
Drug
Policy,
123.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
44
as
large
expenditures
on
the
part
of
local
law
enforcement
and
the
Coast
Guard,
which
could
be
saved
depending
on
how
the
policy
is
changed.150
3.2
The
Case
of
Portugal
The
Portuguese
drug
policy
also
focuses
on
the
concept
of
harm
reduction.
In
the
late
1990s
Portugal
established
a
commission
composed
of
experts
to
examine
the
issue
and
to
make
recommendations
for
improving
drug
policy
in
Portugal.151
The
commission’s
report,
which
strongly
advocated
the
harm
reduction
approach
and
recommended
the
elimination
of
criminal
sanctions
for
drug
use
or
possession,
was
approved
to
the
surprise
of
the
commissioners
and
public.152
The
decriminalization
strategy
is
believed
to
be
the
most
effective
way
to
reduce
usage
and
social
harms,
and
was
never
viewed
as
conceding
that
drug
use
was
inevitable,
which
contrasts
from
the
Dutch
position.153
The
strategy
could
be
described
as
one
seeking
to
implement
a
Pareto
optimal
efficiency:
This
occurs
when
people
are
made
better
off
without
harming
others,
and
this
is
what
the
policy
attempts
to
do.
It
attempts
to
improve
the
lives
of
all
segments
of
Portuguese
society.
The
report
concluded
that
criminalization
created
barriers
to
treatment
and
drained
resources,
which
could
be
more
effectively
allocated
to
reduce
the
problems
associated
with
drug
use.154
150
Nadelmann,
“A
Bad
Export,”
106.
151
Mirjam
van
het
Loo,
Ineke
van
Beusekom,
James
P.
Kahan,
“Decriminalization
of
Drug
Use
in
Portugal:
The
Development
of
a
Policy,”
Annals
of
the
American
Academy
of
Political
and
Social
Science
582,
no.
14
(2002):
50.
152
Loo,
Beusekom,
and
Kahan,
“Decriminalization
of
Drug
Use
in
Portugal,”
50.
153
Glenn
Greenwald,
“Drug
Decriminalization
in
Portugal:
Lessons
for
Creating
Fair
and
Successful
Drug
Policies,”
Cato
Institute,
10.
154
Greenwald,
“Drug
Decriminalization
in
Portugal,”
6.
United
States
Drug
Policy
45
Drugs
were
decriminalized,
but
not
legalized
in
the
new
framework,
which
means
that
that
possession
and
use
are
still
illegal,
but
violations
are
administrative,
not
criminal,
offenses.155
This
new
categorization
is
consistent
with
Portugal’s
international
obligations,
which
under
the
UN
framework
require
use
and
possession
to
be
forbidden,
and
trafficking
to
be
a
criminal
offense.156
The
new
system
has
increased
in
popularity
since
its
inception
because
the
scenarios
that
critics
predicted,
like
Portugal
becoming
a
haven
for
drug
tourists
or
increased
youth
usage
rates,
have
not
occurred.157
Indeed,
95%
of
all
those
receiving
citations
are
Portuguese,
not
foreign
drug
tourists.158
Remarkably,
usage
rates
have
fallen
overall,
and
drug‐related
illnesses,
like
STDs,
have
decreased:
Portugal
now
has
one
of
the
lowest
usage
rates
for
drugs
and
drug‐related
illnesses
in
Europe.159
To
be
more
specific,
usage
of
illicit
substances
among
teenagers,
a
key
target
group,
fell,
and
HIV
infections
caused
by
the
sharing
of
dirty
needles
also
fell,
while
the
level
of
people
seeking
treatment
for
addiction
more
than
doubled.160
Furthermore,
Portugal
now
has
the
lowest
rate
of
marijuana
usage
among
people
over
15
in
the
EU
at
10%.161
Compared
to
the
United
States,
which
measures
lifetime
usage
for
those
over
12
years
old,
Portugal’s
numbers
are
impressive
because
the
U.S.
rate
for
that
group
is
39.8%.162
Interestingly,
a
higher
proportion
of
Americans
have
used
cocaine
than
the
155
Greenwald,
“Drug
Decriminalization
in
Portugal,”
1.
156
Greenwald,
“Drug
Decriminalization
in
Portugal,”
1.
157
Greenwald,
“Drug
Decriminalization
in
Portugal,”
1.
158
Greenwald,
“Drug
Decriminalization
in
Portugal,”
6.
159
Greenwald,
“Drug
Decriminalization
in
Portugal,”
2.
160
Maia
Szalavitz,
“Drugs
in
Portugal:
Did
Decriminalization
Work?,”
Time
Magazine
(Apr.
26,
2009
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.time.com/time/health/article/0,8599,1893946,00.html?xid=rss‐topstories
161
Szalavitz,
“Drugs
in
Portugal”
162
Szalavitz,
“Drugs
in
Portugal”
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
46
proportion
of
Portuguese
that
have
used
marijuana,
which
is
the
most
frequently
used
illicit
substance.163
Portugal
is
the
only
European
state
that
has
explicitly
declared
drugs
to
be
decriminalized,
which
means
removed
from
criminal
law.
Other
European
countries
have
a
de
facto
decriminalization,
especially
for
cannabis
use,
but
Portugal
is
unique
in
that
it
has
a
de
jure
decriminalization
for
all
drugs,
even
cocaine
and
heroin.164
Decriminalization
is
different
from
depenalization
because
depenalization
means
that
possession
and
usage
are
still
subject
to
criminal
law,
however,
no
prison
terms
are
given
for
these
offenses.165
Therefore,
under
depenalization
one
would
still
have
a
criminal
record
if
caught,
whereas
decriminalization
precludes
such
a
record
and
the
associated
social
stigma.
The
relevant
law
states
that:
“the
consumption,
acquisition,
and
possession
for
one’s
own
consumption
of
plants,
substances,
or
preparations
…
constitute
an
administrative
offense.”166
Those
violating
the
law
are
subjected
to
so‐called
dissuasion
commissions
consisting
of
3
members,
one
with
a
legal
background,
and
two
others
with
either
a
medical
or
social
services
background,
which
are
legally
unable
to
mandate
treatment.167
They
do
have
the
ability
to
impose
a
fine
of
no
greater
than
25
Euros,
which
can
be
waived
when
the
defendant
agrees
to
undergo
treatment,
and
can
impose
a
number
of
other
conditions,
for
example:
“suspension
of
the
right
to
practice
a
licensed
profession,
a
ban
on
163
Szalavitz,
“Drugs
in
Portugal”
164
Greenwald,
“Drug
Decriminalization
in
Portugal,”
2.
165
Greenwald,
“Drug
Decriminalization
in
Portugal,”
2.
166
Greenwald,
“Drug
Decriminalization
in
Portugal,”
3.
167
Greenwald,
“Drug
Decriminalization
in
Portugal,”
3.
United
States
Drug
Policy
47
visiting
high‐risk
locales,
a
ban
on
associating
with
specified
individuals,
requiring
periodic
reports
to
the
commission
to
show
there
is
no
ongoing
addiction
or
abuse,
prohibitions
in
travel
abroad,
termination
of
public
benefits
for
subsidies
or
allowances,
or
a
mere
oral
warning.”168
This
contrasts
with
the
American
system
in
which
an
individual
can
only
receive
treatment
by
paying
for
it
directly,
which
is
quite
expensive
and
therefore
impossible
for
a
majority
of
drug
addicts,
or
by
first
being
convicted
in
a
criminal
court
of
law.
We
can
learn
a
few
things
from
the
Portuguese
model.
First,
destigmatization
increased
the
likelihood
that
addicts
will
seek
treatment
because
they
no
longer
must
be
concerned
about
criminal
sanctions.
Second,
destigmatization
increases
the
need
for
treatment,
and
also
the
amount
of
money
necessary
to
fund
it.169
Finally,
and
perhaps
most
importantly,
drug
decriminalization
does
not
always
result
in
increased
use,
especially
over
the
long
term.
This
last
point
is
perhaps
key
to
making
progress
in
the
United
States
and
to
convincing
some
segments
of
the
U.S.
population
that
liberalization
can
have
positive
effects
that
should
not
be
dismissed
out
of
hand.170
168
Greenwald,
“Drug
Decriminalization
in
Portugal,”
3.
169
Loo,
Beusekom,
and
Kahan,
“Decriminalization
of
Drug
Use
in
Portugal,”
58.
170
Szalavitz,
“Drugs
in
Portugal”
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
48
4.
Current
Issues,
Events,
and
Factors
Relevant
to
the
Drug
Policy
Discussion
With
the
election
of
President
Barack
Obama
in
November
of
2008,
a
man
who
has
not
only
admitted
to
drug
use
but
has
also
stated
that
he
inhaled
because
“that
was
the
point”,
the
United
States
may
be
at
a
point
in
time
when
drug
policy
reform
is
not
only
possible,
but
also
necessary.
There
seems
to
be
a
perfect
storm
of
factors
that
indicate
that
this
could
be
an
appropriate
time
to
reevaluate
and
to
reform
the
failed
policy
of
the
last
thirty
years.
Due
to
the
economic
crisis,
the
federal
and
many
state
governments
are
reporting
record
budget
deficits:
the
United
States
deficit
for
fiscal
year
2010
is
estimated
to
be
as
high
as
$1.8
trillion,
and
some
states
like
California
have
budget
shortfalls
in
excess
of
$20
billion.171
Policy
changes
made
earlier
this
year
should
make
things
easier
in
the
case
of
California
because
the
federal
government
will
no
longer
get
in
the
way
of
the
state’s
medical
marijuana
facilities,
and
the
collection
of
over
$100
million
in
associated
tax
revenue,
as
will
be
discussed
below.172
Beyond
the
fiscal
aspect
lies
the
foreign
relations
aspect
of
the
current
policy:
The
Mexican
government
is
presently
in
a
fight
for
its
life
against
traffickers
that
supply
the
American
market,
and
Afghani
militants
derive
a
significant
portion
of
their
income
from
the
international
drug
trade.
According
to
the
2002
ONDCP
strategy,
of
the
28
terrorist
groups
171
Jackie
Calmes,
“Obama
Plans
Major
Shifts
in
Spending,”
New
York
Times
(Feb.
26,
2009
[cited
8
Jul.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/02/27/us/politics/27web‐budget.html
172
Alison
Stateman,
“In
California
Marijuana
Truce,
a
Legal
Grey
Area,”
Time
Magazine
(Mar.
29,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.time.com/time/nation/article/0,8599,1888172,00.html?iid=digg_share
United
States
Drug
Policy
49
identified
by
the
U.S.
State
Department,
12
are
allegedly
involved
in
drug
trafficking.173
Prohibition
could,
therefore,
support
some
of
the
most
dangerous
enemies
of
the
United
States,
which
would
be
one
of
the
most
striking
examples
of
how
the
incoherence
of
various
policies
affect
the
United
States’
vital
interests.
Many
states
in
the
U.S.
have
passed,
or
will
pass,
medical
marijuana
legislation
while
permissive
opinions
about
drugs
are
at
an
all
time
high,
particularly
concerning
marijuana.
These
are
just
some
of
the
factors
that
indicate
now
might
be
the
right
time
to
think
about
making
significant
changes
to
drug
policy
in
the
United
States.
4.1
Current
Trends
Certainly
support
for
marijuana
legalization
has
risen
to
record
levels
over
the
last
few
years:
a
recently
commissioned
Zogby
poll
found
that
44
percent
of
likely
American
voters
support
the
legalization
on
cannabis,
and
that
the
substance
should
be
regulated
and
taxed
like
alcohol
and
tobacco.174
Barring
any
unforeseen
high‐impact
news
events,
it
is
likely
that
over
the
next
decade
a
majority
of
Americans
will
support
legalization
of
marijuana
at
minimum.
To
be
clear,
the
poll
indicated
that
support
was
for
legalization,
not
for
medical
marijuana,
which
is
most
likely
supported
by
a
higher
proportion
of
Americans
because
it
is
a
less
extreme
measure.
Some
recognizable
U.S.
politicians
have
also
been
more
aggressive
lately
in
their
activities
supporting
liberalization
of
marijuana.
Congressman
Barney
Frank
recently
introduced
a
173
Robinson
and
Scherlen,
“Lies,
Damned
Lies,”
150.
174
Paul
Armentano,
“ABC
News:
Public
Support
for
Pot
Legalization
Has
Never
Been
Higher!,”
NORML
(Apr.
30,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://blog.norml.org/2009/04/30/abc‐news‐publics‐support‐for‐pot‐legalization‐has‐ never‐been‐higher/
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
50
bill
called
the
Personal
Use
of
Marijuana
by
Responsible
Adults
Act
of
2009,
which
would
eliminate
federal
penalties
for
possession
of
less
than
100
grams
of
marijuana,
and
would
mandate
a
small
$100
fine
for
use
in
public.175
When
asked
about
his
bill
he
stated
“I
think
John
Stuart
Mill
had
it
right
in
the
1850s
when
he
argued
that
individuals
should
have
the
right
to
do
what
they
want
in
private,
so
long
as
they
don’t
hurt
anyone
else.
It’s
a
matter
of
personal
liberty.
Moreover,
our
courts
are
already
stressed
and
our
prisons
are
over‐crowded.
We
don’t
need
to
spend
our
scarce
resources
prosecuting
people
who
are
doing
no
harm
to
others.”176
In
addition
he
stated
recently
in
an
interview,
Announcing
that
the
government
should
mind
its
own
business
on
marijuana
is
really
not
that
hard.
There's
not
a
lot
of
complexity
here.
We
should
stop
treating
people
as
criminals
because
they
smoke
marijuana.
The
problem
is
the
political
will.
This
is
a
case
where
there's
cultural
lag
on
the
part
of
my
colleagues.
If
you
ask
them
privately,
they
don't
think
it's
a
terrible
thing.
But
they're
afraid
of
being
portrayed
as
soft
on
drugs.
And
by
the
way,
the
argument
is,
nobody
ever
gets
arrested
for
it.
But
we
have
this
outrageous
case
in
New
York
where
a
cop
jammed
a
baton
up
a
guy's
ass
when
he
caught
him
smoking
marijuana.177
This
personal
liberty
aspect
of
drug
policy
is
one
upon
which
this
paper
has
not
yet
touched.
The
main
question
to
be
considered
along
these
lines
is
to
what
degree
can
a
government
limit
what
a
citizen
chooses
to
put
175
Anonymous,
“Barney
Frank
Files
Bill
to
Decriminalize
Pot,”
wbztv
(Jun.
19
2009
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://wbztv.com/local/marijuana.federal.penalty.2.1052437.html
176
Anonymous,
Barney
Frank
Files
Bill
to
Decriminalize
Pot
177
John
H.
Richardson,
“He’s
Not
High:
Inside
Barney
Frank's
Plan
to
Legalize
Marijuana,”
Esquire
Magazine
(Jul.
14,
2009
[cited
16
Jul.
2009]):
available
at
http://www.esquire.com/the‐side/richardson‐report/new‐marijuana‐laws‐ 071309?src=digg
United
States
Drug
Policy
51
into
his
own
body
in
a
free
society?
If
it
is
assumed
that
such
a
power
to
limit
consumption
exists,
how
does
that
relate
to
a
free
society?
Does
one
own
one’s
own
body?
If
so
then
no
real
limitations
on
consumption
of
illicit
substances
are
compatible
with
self‐ownership.
If
it
is
accepted
that
government
can
rightly
limit
bodily
consumption
of
substances
for
the
reason
that
this
consumption
has
negative
external
effects,
what
else
is
acceptable
for
the
same
reason?
These
are
all
important
philosophical
questions
to
consider,
but
they
are
not
the
main
focus
of
this
paper,
so
we
cannot
examine
them
here
in
greater
detail.
Some
progress
has
already
been
made
towards
liberalization
in
Obama’s
young
administration.
One
notable
event
occurred
earlier
in
the
year
when
the
new
Drug
Czar
called
for
the
end
of
the
use
of
the
term
“war
on
drugs”,
reflecting
the
fact
that
views
are
changing
in
Washington
and
that
the
administration
understands
that
the
term
has
not
been
particularly
useful
in
framing
the
debate
on
drug
policy.178
When
explaining
the
decision
Gil
Kerlikowske,
current
U.S.
Drug
Czar,
averred
“Regardless
of
how
you
try
to
explain
to
people
it’s
a
‘war
on
drugs’
or
a
‘war
on
a
product,’
people
see
a
war
as
a
war
on
them.
We’re
not
at
war
with
people
in
this
country.”179
Moreover,
Mr.
Kerlikowske
made
the
following
statement
indicating
further
changes
in
how
Washington
might
approach
the
problem
The
Obama
Administration
understands
addiction
is
a
disease,
and
its
treatment
needs
to
be
addressed
as
part
of
a
comprehensive
strategy
178
Gary
Fields,
“White
House
Czar
Calls
for
End
to
‘War
on
Drugs’,”
Wall
Street
Journal
(May
14,
2009
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB124225891527617397.html?
179
Fields,
“White
House
Czar”
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
52
to
stop
drug
use.
Research
shows
addiction
is
a
complex,
biological,
and
psychological
disorder.
It
is
progressive
and
chronic,
and
negatively
affects
individuals,
families,
communities,
and
society.
In
2007,
over
20
million
individuals
in
our
country
(12
and
older)
were
diagnosed
with
substance
dependence
or
abuse.
However,
less
than
10%
received
treatment
for
their
disorder.180
Earlier
this
year
U.S.
Attorney
General
Eric
Holder
announced
that
the
administration
will
halt
actions
against
marijuana
dispensaries
in
California.181
The
logic
behind
the
decision
was
that
federal
resources
should
not
be
used
to
trump
state
laws,
and
that
states
should
be
able
to
set
their
own
policies
on
this
issue.182
This
announcement
has
been
viewed
as
an
extremely
important
event
in
the
struggle
for
liberalization
of
marijuana
laws,
and
as
a
result
several
states
have
passed
legislation
to
legalize
the
drug,
Rhode
Island
for
instance.183
James
Pasco,
executive
director
of
the
Fraternal
Order
of
Police
recently
stated
that,
while
he
has
respect
for
the
new
Drug
Czar,
“I
don’t
necessarily
disagree
with
Gil’s
focus
on
treatment
and
demand
reduction,
I
don’t
want
to
see
it
at
the
expense
of
law
enforcement.
People
need
to
understand
that
when
they
violate
the
law
there
are
consequences.”184
This
represents
the
policy
perspective
of
the
law
180
Kerlikowske,
“Domestic
Policy
Subcommittee”
181
Bob
Egelko,
“U.S.
to
Yield
Marijuana
Jurisdiction
to
States,”
San
Francisco
Chronicle
(Feb
27,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.sfgate.com/cgi‐ bin/article.cgi?file=/c/a/2009/02/27/MN2016651R.DTL
182
Egelko,
“U.S.
to
Yield
Marijuana”
183
Karl
Vick,
“In
Calif.,
Medical
Marijuana
Laws
Are
Moving
Pot
Into
the
Mainstream,”
Washington
Post
(Apr.
12,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp‐ dyn/content/article/2009/04/11/AR2009041100767.html?referrer=digg
184
Fields,
“White
House
Czar”
United
States
Drug
Policy
53
enforcement
stakeholders,
that
they
support
changes
as
long
as
they
do
not
affect
their
power
or
turf,
which
they
rhetorically
refer
to
as
law
enforcement.
Prosecutions
will
continue
under
the
new
policy
only
when
dispensaries
are
in
violation
of
both
federal
and
state
laws,
which
means
that
federal
enforcement
will
be
somewhat
of
a
grey
area
until
the
law
is
clarified.185
In
Rhode
Island’s
case
the
legislation
had
so
much
support
among
the
state
house
and
senate
that
it
was
passed
by
overriding
the
veto
of
the
governor,
who
argued
that
passage
of
the
bill
would
send
the
wrong
message
to
children
and
invite
federal
prosecutions.186
In
all,
ten
states
have
reduced
penalties
for
possessing
marijuana
for
personal
use
including:
California,
Colorado,
Maine,
Minnesota,
Mississippi,
Nebraska,
Nevada,
New
York,
North
Carolina,
and
Oregon.187
Beyond
this,
13
states
have
legalized
medical
marijuana,
a
trend
that
has
been
associated
with
holistic,
or
alternative,
medicine,
and
six
states,
including
Delaware,
Illinois,
Iowa,
New
Hampshire,
New
Jersey,
and
Pennsylvania
are
considering
similar
legislation.188
Due
to
changes
in
public
opinion
and
state
laws,
the
federal
government
may
have
to
change
its
classification
of
marijuana
as
a
schedule
1
drug,
which
means
that
it
currently
has
no
accepted
medical
use,
and
that
the
danger
of
addiction
is
high,
to
a
lower
classification
because
of
increasing
public
support
for
the
185
Stateman,
In
California
Marijuana
Truce,
a
Legal
Gray
Area
186
Nancy
Krause,
“RI
Senate
Approves
Marijuana
Stores,”
WPRI
(Jun
10,
2009
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.wpri.com/dpp/news/local_news/local_wpri_providence_senate_passes_medical _marijuana_compassion_center_bill_20090609_nek
187
Anonymous,
Barney
Frank
Files
Bill
to
Decriminalize
Pot
188
Ray
Henry,
“RI
Becomes
3rd
State
Allowing
Marijuana
Stores,”
The
Boston
Globe
(Jun.
16
2009
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.boston.com/news/local/rhode_island/articles/2009/06/16/ri_becomes_3rd_st ate_allowing_marijuana_stores_1245192510/
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
54
liberalization
of
the
policy.189
Even
this
small
change
would
be
a
stark
contrast
to
the
policy
of
the
Bush
administration,
which
blocked
at
least
one
study
by
the
University
of
Massachusetts
that
would
have
tried
to
determine
the
medically
applicable
properties
of
marijuana.190
More
and
more
people
are
recognizing
that,
even
though
it
is
not
a
mainstream
opinion
of
physicians,
marijuana
may
have
some
benefits,
and
at
the
very
least
should
be
researched
so
an
answer
to
that
question
can
be
found.
Former
Seattle
police
chief,
Norm
Stamper,
believes
that
the
momentum
of
public
debate
on
the
topic
of
marijuana
liberalization
has
recently
increased,
and
he
stated
“What
we’ve
seen
in
the
past
six
months
is
an
explosion
of
activity,
fresh
thinking,
bold
statements,
and
penetrating
questions”
while
characterizing
the
previous
20
years
as
only
having
made
incremental
progress.191
Additional
changes
that
are
expected
to
happen
with
the
approval
of
congress
are
the
end
to
needle
exchange
prohibitions
and
an
increase
in
treatment,
possibly
in
conjunction
with
drug
courts.192
Funding
for
drug
courts
was
increased
by
250%
in
March,
which
represents
the
realization
of
a
campaign
promise
of
Obama,
and
is
consistent
with
a
statement
of
Vice
President
Joe
Biden,
who
said
drug
courts
“can
serve
as
the
light
at
the
end
of
the
tunnel,
of
a
very
long,
long
dark
tunnel,
for
those
who
are
stuck
in
the
cycle
of
drug
addiction
and
incarceration.”193
189
Vick,
“In
Calif.,
Medical
Marijuana”
190
Egelko,
“U.S.
to
Yield
Marijuana”
191
Crary,
Momentum
Builds
for
Broad
Debate
on
Legalizing
Pot
192
Fields,
“White
House
Czar”
193
Acosta
and
Keck,
“White
House
Tries
to
Combat,”
United
States
Drug
Policy
55
4.2
Medical
Marijuana
An
increasing,
albeit
controversial,
body
of
scientific
evidence
suggests
that
marijuana
should
be
available
to
patients
afflicted
with
numerous
illnesses
including
glaucoma,
cancer,
and
AIDS.
Marijuana
has
been
demonstrated
to
be
an
effective
pain
reliever,
and
has
been
able
to
stimulate
the
appetites
of
cancer
and
AIDS
patients.
During
recent
testimony
in
the
Senate
Health,
Housing
and
Family
Security
Committee
several
people
testified
about
the
beneficial
effects
marijuana
had
had
for
their
loved
ones,
including
one
who
stated
her
mother,
a
cancer
sufferer,
smoked
marijuana
and
after
“two
minutes…and
the
violent
sickness
was
totally
gone.
An
hour
later,
Mom
was
able
to
have
a
good
meal.
The
stomach
problems
from
the
chemo
were
totally
gone.
It
also
helped
her
regain
a
quality
of
life
that
allowed
her
to
continue
to
fight.”194
Detractors,
however,
have
pointed
out
some
of
marijuana’s
bad
effects,
like
short‐term
memory
loss,
diminished
learning
capacity,
and
the
creation
of
passive
individuals
who
lack
motivation.195
Further,
they
contend
that
legalization
increases
use,
which
increases
the
already
high
associated
social
costs
by
increasing
accidents
and
healthcare
costs,
and
by
decreasing
productivity.196
Clearly
there
are
negative
externalities
born
by
others
including:
increased
unemployment
insurance
payments,
lower
output,
194
Andy
Birkey,
“Medical
Marijuana
Bill
Advances
in
Senate
with
Moving
Testimony,”
Minnesota
Independent
(Feb.
12,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://minnesotaindependent.com/26340/medical‐marijuana‐bill‐advances‐in‐senate‐with‐ moving‐testimony
195
Collins,
Holland’s
HalfBaked
Drug
Experiment,
87.
196
Kevin
A.
Sabet,
“The
Price
of
Legalizing
Pot
is
too
High,”
Los
Angeles
Times
(Jun.
7,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.latimes.com/news/la‐oe‐sabet7‐ 2009jun07,0,5717495.story?track=rss
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
56
lower
returns
on
investments
in
human
capital,
and
increased
turnover.197
While
there
certainly
are
negative
effects
associated
with
the
use
of
marijuana,
the
positive
benefits
of
using
marijuana
as
a
part
of
certain
treatment
regimes
certainly
seems
to
warrant
a
greater
commitment
on
the
part
of
policy
makers
to
fund
research
in
this
area,
or
at
least
to
not
prohibit
it,
so
informed
decisions
can
be
properly
made.
Those
negative
effects
may
be
especially
hazardous
for
adolescent
users
and
they
include
genetic
and
reproductive
effects,
and
potential
cancer
effects.198
It
seems
to
be
a
consensus
opinion
that
marijuana
potency
has
increased
over
the
last
three
decades,
which
is
consistent
with
the
effects
of
prohibition,
so
it
is
likely
that
the
considerations
of
policy
makers
have
also
changed
during
this
period,
and
any
analysis
of
the
medical
efficacy
of
marijuana,
or
other
currently
illicit
drugs
for
that
matter,
should
therefore
be
reconsidered
or
evaluated
on
a
periodic
basis.
After
the
recent
legalization
of
medical
marijuana
in
Oregon,
President
Obama
was
asked
if
he
would
“stop
the
DEA’s
raids
on
Oregon
medical
marijuana
growers”
and
he
responded
“I
would
because
our
federal
agents
have
better
things
to
do,
like
catching
criminals
and
preventing
terrorism.
The
way
I
want
to
approach
the
issue
of
medical
marijuana
is
to
base
it
on
science,
and
if
there
is
sound
science
that
supports
the
use
of
medical
marijuana
and
if
it
is
controlled
and
prescribed
in
the
way
that
other
medicine
is
prescribed,
then
it’s
something
that
I
think
we
should
197
Jeff
DeSimone,
“Illegal
Drug
Use
and
Employment,”
Journal
of
Labor
Economics
20,
no.
4
(2002):
970.
198
Edward
A.
Jacobs,
“Marijuana
and
Adolescents,”
The
Institute
on
Global
Drug
Policy
[cited
on
25
Jun.
2009]:
available
from
http://www.globaldrugpolicy.org/1/1/3.php
United
States
Drug
Policy
57
consider.”199
This
statement
reflects
the
opinion
of
a
majority
of
citizens
as
reported
by
a
Zogby
poll
that
found
that
72%
of
Americans
support
ending
these
DEA
raids
on
medical
marijuana
facilities.200
This
is
an
interesting
statement
for
several
reasons:
First,
it
recognizes
that
there
is
an
opportunity
cost
associated
with
fighting
the
drug
war,
namely
that
enforcement
diverts
resources
away
from
fighting
crimes
with
actual
victims;
second,
he
claims
to
want
policies
based
on
science,
though
it
is
too
soon
to
evaluate
his
sincerity;
and
finally,
the
statement
makes
clear
that
President
Obama
would
support
having
the
same
controls
on
marijuana
as
exist
on
other
prescription
drugs.
All
three
points
indicate
that
Obama
is
far
more
receptive
to
the
idea
of
liberalization
of
drug
policy
than
any
president
in
the
last
30
years,
and
this
is
one
reason
that
there
is
a
real
opportunity
for
reform
during
Obama’s
presidency.
The
first
state
to
adopt
a
medical
marijuana
policy
was
California
through
the
Compassionate
Use
Act
of
1996,
the
purpose
of
which
was
to:
To
ensure
that
seriously
ill
Californians
have
the
right
to
obtain
and
use
marijuana
for
medical
purposes
where
the
medical
use
is
deemed
appropriate
and
has
been
recommended
by
a
physician
who
has
determined
that
the
person's
health
would
benefit
from
the
use
of
marijuana
in
the
treatment
of
cancer,
anorexia,
AIDS,
chronic
pain,
spasticity,
glaucoma,
arthritis,
migraine,
or
any
other
illness
for
which
marijuana
provides
relief;
and
to
ensure
that
patients
and
their
primary
caregivers
199
Robert
L.
DuPont,
“Barack
Obama
on
Medical
Marijuana,”
The
Institute
on
Global
Drug
Policy
[cited
25
Jun.
2009]:
available
from
http://www.globaldrugpolicy.org/3/1/commentary.php
200
Anonymous,
“72%
Want
Obama
to
End
DEA
Raids,”
Obamawerds
(Feb
4,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009])
available
from
http://obamawerds.com/articles/viewArticle/72_want_Obama_to_end_DEA_raids
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
58
who
obtain
and
use
marijuana
for
medical
purposes
upon
the
recommendation
of
a
physician
are
not
subject
to
criminal
prosecution
or
sanction."201
Since
the
passage
of
this
law
the
use
of
medical
marijuana
to
treat
various
conditions
has
increased;
the
most
common
illnesses
treated
with
medical
marijuana
are:
40%
chronic
pain,
22%
AIDS
related,
15%
mood
disorders,
and
23%
for
all
other
categories.202
In
California
the
use
of
marijuana
as
a
medicine
has
normalized
and
is
no
longer
controversial
within
the
state.203
Due
to
a
recent
Supreme
Court
ruling,
the
last
bastions
of
opposition
against
the
medical
marijuana
law’s
full
implementation
have
been
defeated
and
dispensaries
will
soon
be
opening
in
these
locations.
The
1996
law
requires
local
governments
to
issue
medical
marijuana
identification
cards,
which
more
conservative
places
like
San
Diego
have
long
opposed,
that
are
designed
to
identify
legal
customers
in
the
dispensaries
and
to
show
to
police
to
prevent
arrest.204
San
Diego
filed
suit
in
2006
on
the
grounds
that
the
federal
prohibition
of
marijuana
supersedes
state
law,
and
therefore
there
is
no
legal
requirement
for
them
to
implement
the
law.205
San
Diego
lost
the
case
and
the
appeal,
so
the
city
government
appealed
to
the
U.S.
Supreme
Court,
which
declined
to
hear
the
case.206
This
means
that
the
ruling
of
the
lower
court
stands
and
they
must
then
201
Anonymous,
“Medical
Marijuana,”
The
Medical
Board
of
California
(May
7,
2004
[cited
10
Jul.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.medbd.ca.gov/medical_marijuana.html
202
Anonymous,
“California
Medical
Marijuana
Information,”
U.S.
Drug
Enforcement
Agency
[cited
10
Jul.
2009]:
available
from
http://www.medbd.ca.gov/medical_marijuana.html
203
Vick,
“In
Calif.,
Medical
Marijuana”
204
Ryan
Grim,
“Supreme
Court
Hands
Medical
Marijuana
Major
Victory,”
The
Huffington
Post
(May
18,
2009
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
http://www.huffingtonpost.com/2009/05/18/supreme‐court‐hands‐medic_n_204681.html
205
Grim,
Supreme
Court
Hands
Medical
Marijuana
Major
Victory
206
Grim,
Supreme
Court
Hands
Medical
Marijuana
Major
Victory
United
States
Drug
Policy
59
implement
the
medical
marijuana
identification
card
program.
Interestingly,
since
the
announcement
of
Attorney
General
Eric
Holder
on
February
26,
2009,
new
applications
for
retail
locations
have
ballooned
in
Los
Angeles.
California
is
also
at
the
forefront
of
the
treatment
approach
for
dealing
with
convicted
offenders.
In
2000,
California
passed
Proposition
36,
which
mandated
that
convicted
adult
drug
offenders
be
offered
treatment
instead
of
incarceration,
over
the
objections
of
the
law
enforcement
and
other
stakeholders.207
The
importance
of
California
in
this
debate
is
that
it
serves
as
a
case
study,
and
allows
the
country
to
observe
the
developments
there.
Citizens
can
see
that
the
state
is
not
rapidly
deteriorating
and
that
criminality
is
not
increasing
due
to
the
medicalization
of
marijuana,
which
in
effect
can
be
acquired
by
anyone
who
tells
his
doctor
that
he
thinks
it
would
benefit
him
somehow.
4.3
Foreign
Impact
of
Drug
Prohibition:
Current
Developments
in
Mexico
Americans
have
watched
in
horror
as
the
security
situation
in
Mexico
has
rapidly
declined
since
Mexican
President
Felipe
Calderon
launched
an
all
out
offensive
against
traffickers
in
2006,
which
has
cost
an
estimated
$6.4
billion
and
has
involved
45,000
soldiers.208
Since
then,
nearly
11,000
lives
have
been
lost
as
the
government
fights
the
cartels
to
reacquire
control
of
the
country:
this
includes
over
6,000
deaths
in
2008,
and
over
1,000
deaths
so
207
Dorie
Klein,
“Incorporating
a
Public
Health
Approach
in
Drug
Law:
Lessons
from
Local
Expansion
of
Treatment
Capacity
and
Access
under
California’s
Proposition
36,”
The
Milbank
Quarterly
82,
no.
4
(2004):
723.
208
Julie
Watson
“It’s
Police
vs.
Police
in
Mexican
Drug
War,”
The
Star
(Jun.
10,
2009
{cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.thestar.com/news/world/article/648303
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
60
far
in
2009.209
Violence
is
so
bad
in
the
north
of
Mexico
that
the
U.S.
state
department
has
issued
travel
warnings
including
a
warning
to
students
that
they
should
not
travel
to
Mexico
during
spring
break.
Within
Mexico
the
situation
is
far
more
violent
in
the
north,
with
60%
of
drug‐related
murders
occurring
in
the
northern
states
of
Chihuahua,
Baja
California,
Sinaloa,
and
Durango.210
At
the
end
of
the
Bush
administration,
Secretary
of
Homeland
Security,
Michael
Chertoff,
spoke
about
military
plans
that
would
provide
a
response
crossing
Mexico’s
border
in
the
event
that
the
violence
spilled
into
the
United
States
proper.
Within
the
United
States
the
administration
will
spend
$184
million
to
hire
an
additional
360
security
personnel
to
bolster
border
areas
to
increase
the
effectiveness
of
the
border
checks.211
The
United
States
is
also
cooperating
with
Mexican
authorities
by
helping
them
conduct
raids
designed
to
capture
cartel
members
and
corrupt
police,
and
by
providing
monetary
assistance
and
military
hardware
to
increase
the
effectiveness
of
the
Mexican
anti‐cartel
strategy.212
The
Obama
administration
has
pledged
$725
million
to
modernize
border
areas,
and
will
pay
an
additional
$80
million
to
outfit
the
Mexican
forces
engaged
against
the
cartels.213
At
the
same
time
Mexican
cartels
have
begun
to
plant
marijuana
crops
within
the
United
States,
often
in
state
and
federal
parks,
to
avoid
the
209
Tim
Rutten,
“The
War
We
Gave
Mexico,”
Los
Angeles
Times
(Feb.
28,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009])
available
from
http://www.latimes.com/news/opinion/sunday/commentary/la‐oe‐ rutten28‐2009feb28,0,2564151.column
210
Mary
Anastasia
O'Grady,
“A
Stimulus
Plan
for
Mexican
Gangsters,”
The
Wall
Street
Journal
(Mar.
2,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB123595140575504953.html
211
Arshad
Mohammed,
“U.S.
to
Blame
for
Much
of
Mexico
Violence:
Clinton,”
Reuters
(Mar.
25,
2009
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.reuters.com/article/topNews/idUSTRE52O5RF20090325?feedType=R%20SS& feedName=topNews&rpc=22&sp=true.
212
Emilio
San
Pedro,
“U.S.
Ready
to
Aid
Mexico
Drug
Fight,”
BBC
(Mar.
2,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/americas/7918101.stm
213
Mohammed,
U.S.
to
Blame
for
Much
of
Mexico
Violence:
Clinton
United
States
Drug
Policy
61
need
to
smuggle
the
product
across
the
border;
in
California
alone
2.9
million
plants
were
uprooted
by
the
end
of
last
year.214
This
indicates
that,
not
unexpectedly,
the
cartels
are
responding
to
changing
enforcement
patterns
and
are
adapting
their
operations
to
compensate
for
them.
As
Mexico
and
the
United
States
have
ratcheted
up
their
response
to
the
cartels
and
traffickers,
so
have
the
cartels
responded
with
increased
violence
and
increased
bribes,
which
is
one
remarkable
effect
of
prohibition
enforcement
that
was
discussed
in
the
first
section.215
One
response,
which
has
drawn
the
ire
of
2nd
Amendment
advocates,
suggested
by
Attorney
General
Eric
Holder,
should
be
the
restoration
of
prohibitions
against
assault
weapons
in
the
United
States.216
The
logic
of
this
move
would
be
to
eliminate
these
weapons
in
the
United
States
to
prevent
their
illegal
exportation
into
Mexico;
a
trend
the
administration
insists
is
large
and
growing.217
In
her
recent
visit
to
Mexico
City,
Secretary
of
State
Hillary
Rodham
Clinton
said
the
following:
“Our
insatiable
demand
for
illegal
drugs
fuels
the
drug
trade.
Our
inability
to
prevent
weapons
from
being
illegally
smuggled
across
the
border
to
arm
these
criminals
causes
the
death
of
police
officers,
soldier
and
civilians.”218
The
argument
that
about
90%
of
all
guns
recovered
in
Mexico
originate
in
the
United
States
has
been
increasingly
questioned.
Apparently
the
figure
accounts
for
only
the
proportion
of
guns
that
Mexico
submits
for
214
Solomon
Moore,
“Tougher
Border
Can’t
Stop
Mexican
Marijuana
Cartels,”
New
York
Times
(Feb.
1,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/02/02/us/02pot.html?ex=1391317200&en=bd77410a2ec4 8dbd&ei=5124&partner=digg&exprod=digg
215
Rutten,
The
War
We
Gave
Mexico
216
Rutten,
The
War
We
Gave
Mexico
217
Mohammed,
U.S.
to
Blame
for
Much
of
Mexico
Violence:
Clinton
218
Mohammed,
U.S.
to
Blame
for
Much
of
Mexico
Violence:
Clinton
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
62
tracing,
and
Mexico
apparently
only
submits
those
guns
that
it
suspects
are
of
U.S.
origin.219
The
increased
violence
has
also
caught
the
attention
of
the
state
governments
bordering
Mexico.
The
Democratic
Attorney
General
of
Arizona,
Terry
Goddard,
recently
indicated
that
legalization
should
be
part
of
the
debate
concerning
how
to
control
violence
and
prevent
it
from
crossing
the
border.220
When
asked
about
his
opinion
on
the
legalization
issue,
Attorney
General
Goddard
said:
“We
need
to
find
a
better
way
to
handle
…
right
now
the
item
that’s
fueling
the
violent
cartels,
the
murders
in
Mexico,
the
cartel
wars
that
are
going
on
right
now
that
have
resulted
in
over
1,000
deaths
this
year,
I
think
we
need
to
take
a
very
aggressive
stand
on
that
and
marijuana
is
the
number
one
producer
for
the
cartels.
Sixty
to
seventy
percent
of
their
gross
profits
come
from
marijuana.
So,
I
think
we
need
to
look
very
hard
at
something
we
haven’t
looked
at
for
years.”221
Former
Bush
Administration
Drug
Czar
Barry
McCaffrey
recently
stated
that
“Mexico
is
on
the
edge
of
the
abyss”
of
becoming
“a
narco‐state”
referring
to
the
increasing
violence
in
the
country.222
The
Mexican
government
also
estimates
that
the
majority
of
drug
cartel
revenue
is
raised
through
the
marijuana
trade
so
policies
that
eliminate
or
greatly
reduce
the
money
they
can
raise
from
marijuana
would
have
a
219
Stossel,
Prohibition
Spawns
Drug
Violence
220
David
Edwards
and
Stephen
C.
Webster,
“Arizona
AG:
Pot
Legalization
Could
Prevent
Border
Violence,”
The
Raw
Story
(Feb.
27,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://rawstory.com/news/2008/Arizona_AG_Pot_legalization_could_prevent_0227.html
221
Edwards
and
Webster,
Arizona
AG:
Pot
Legalization
Could
Prevent
Border
Violence
222
Anonymous,
“Editorial:
Front
Line:
Mexico,”
The
Philadelphia
Inquirer
(Mar.
1,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.philly.com/inquirer/currents/20090301_Editorial__Front_Line__Mexico.html?re ferrer=digg.
United
States
Drug
Policy
63
strong
effect
on
cartels
as
they
are
currently
organized.223
The
main
goal
according
to
a
host
of
U.S.
officials
should
be
to
prevent
the
north
Mexican
violence
from
spreading
into
the
southern
United
States.
Former
Colombian
president
César
Gaviria,
who
was
an
important
figure
in
the
drug
war
in
the
1990s,
recently
stated,
“The
fight
against
drug
cartels
is
unavoidable.
If
you
don’t
do
it,
they
become
too
powerful
and
may
even
pose
a
military
threat,
as
we
saw
in
Colombia.
But
that
does
not
mean
that
such
efforts
reduce
the
flow
of
drugs.”224
In
fact,
the
Latin
American
Commission
on
Drugs
and
Democracy,
which
Gaviria
and
a
number
of
other
former
Latin
American
presidents
founded
to
create
a
forum
to
discuss
international
drug
policy,
advocates
the
decriminalization
of
all
drugs,
not
just
soft‐drugs,
as
the
best
method
to
increase
international
security
and
diminish
the
influence
of
the
cartels.225
The
commission
concedes
that
international
enforcement
efforts
can
be
effective
in
restoring
order
to
a
country
and
expanding
the
influence
of
its
democratically
elected
government,
however,
the
commission
believes
that
to
achieve
long‐term
stability
and
security,
demand
in
the
United
States,
the
world’s
largest
drug
market,
must
be
reduced
or
eliminated,
and
the
most
effective
way
to
achieve
that
goal
is
to
decriminalize
drugs.226
Beyond
these
recommendations,
the
commission
has
advocated
a
harm
reduction
approach
that
focuses
on
treatment
as
a
way
to
reduce
crime
and
dependency:
former
president
Gaviria
recently
stated
that
“if
you
don’t
help
those
who
are
223
O'Grady,
A
Stimulus
Plan
for
Mexican
Gangsters
224
Constantino
Diaz‐Duran,
“America
Should
Decriminalize
Drugs,”
The
Daily
Beast
(Apr.
19,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.thedailybeast.com/blogs‐and‐ stories/2009‐04‐19/drug‐war‐lessons‐from‐colombia/
225
Diaz‐Duran,
America
Should
Decriminalize
Drugs
226
Diaz‐Duran,
America
Should
Decriminalize
Drugs
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
64
dependent,
you
are
half
way
there
because
they
are
going
to
commit
crime
to
get
money
and
pay
for
the
drug.”227
The
focus
on
the
demand‐side
is
consistent
with
the
rhetoric
of
the
new
Obama
administration,
but
the
idea
that
legalization
can
be
used
to
undercut
the
drug
cartels
reflects
an
option
that
is
not
yet
on
the
table
according
to
Secretary
of
Homeland
Security,
Janet
Napolitano.228
5.
Potential
Policy
Frameworks
Thus
far
we
have
considered
a
wide
variety
perspectives
relevant
to
the
discussion
about
U.S.
drug
policy.
To
review,
we
have
considered
the
economic
effects
of
prohibition
in
general;
we
have
reviewed
the
drug
policy
since
circa
1979;
we
have
seen
how
the
drug
policies
of
Holland
and
Portugal
differ
from
the
U.S.
policy
and
why
the
differences
matter;
and
finally
we
have
learned
in
what
ways
Obama
and
his
administration
differ,
and
might
further
differ,
from
the
administrations
of
the
last
30
years.
While
it
is
interesting
to
consider
trends
and
past
policies,
any
document
without
some
form
of
recommendation
is
of
questionable
usefulness.
In
order
to
achieve
this
objective,
a
discussion
of
3
general
policy
frameworks,
or
perspectives,
will
be
discussed
that
will
give
the
reader
a
general
sense
of
what
is
possible.
The
three
policy
options
that
will
be
considered
are,
in
the
order
of
ascending
likelihood:
the
libertarian
model
or
legalization,
the
decriminalization
model,
and
finally
the
depenalization
model.
The
reader
should
keep
in
mind
that
a
227
Anonymous,
“Ex‐presidents
of
Latin
America
Urge
Legal
Marijuana,”
CNN
(Feb.
11,
2009
[23
Feb.
2009]):
available
from
http://edition.cnn.com/2009/WORLD/americas/02/11/brazil.marijuana/index.html
228
Acosta
and
Keck,
“White
House
Tries
to
Combat”
United
States
Drug
Policy
65
certain
generality
will
be
maintained
in
this
section,
while
the
final
recommendation
will
be
more
specific.
Before
beginning
with
the
discussion
of
policy
options
it
is
important
at
this
point
to
discuss
the
various
stakeholders
that
are
likely
to
take
part
in
any
deliberative
process
regarding
drug
policy,
and
who
are
perhaps
powerful
enough
to
block
certain
reforms
or
changes
from
happening.
The
first
group
to
consider
is
the
liberalization
advocates.
This
group
at
a
minimum
supports
medical
marijuana,
and
at
the
maximum
supports
a
complete
decriminalization
or
legalization
of
drugs.
It
contains
a
wide
variety
of
groups
including:
left
civil
libertarians,
right
free‐marketeers,
libertarians,
harm
reduction
advocates
within
the
government,
and
certain
compassionate
care
advocates.
This
group
has
been
growing
lately
as
has
been
discussed,
but
the
constituent
groups
are
dispersed
across
the
political
spectrum.
The
next
group
to
be
discussed
is
the
pharmacological
group.
This
group
enjoys
its
monopoly
on
drug
creation
and
distribution,
and
will
advocate
against
anything
that
could
threaten
the
status
quo
in
that
area,
including
medical
marijuana.
This
group
is
powerful
and
employs
many
lobbyists.
The
entrenched
supporters
of
the
present
policy
within
government
constitute
the
next
group.
The
group
includes
members
of
the
20
or
more
agencies
that
receive
funding
to
combat
the
drug
trade
and
are
coordinated
by
the
ONDCP;
the
CIA,
which
may
be
involved
in
clandestine
operations
that
even
directly
support
the
drug
trade;
police
organizations
around
the
country
that
receive
funding
and
enjoy
the
militarization
of
their
forces
and
the
increased
power
the
present
policy
gives
them;
and
members
of
the
federal,
state,
and
local
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
66
prison
systems,
which
derive
funding
based
on
their
number
of
prisoners,
and
which
define
success
in
terms
of
funding
increases.
Another
powerful
group
against
any
liberalization
of
drug
policy
is
the
moralist
Christian
right,
which
believes
that
drugs
are
de
facto
immoral
and
should
be
prohibited
to
prevent
people
from
engaging
in
immorality.
This
group
is
private,
well
funded,
and
is
politically
allied
with
the
Republican
Party
where
it
constitutes
a
significant
wing
of
the
party.
Among
the
relevant
groups
this
group
is
most
likely
to
be
against
liberalization
on
a
fundamentalist
level,
as
they
believe
that
it
is
their
duty
to
inspire
or
force
moral
behavior
on
the
rest
of
society.
Among
the
various
stakeholders
there
are
differences;
some
are
dispersed
across
the
political
spectrum
and
some
are
concentrated;
some
represent
narrow
interests
and
some
represent
broad
interests;
and
some
are
likely
to
be
marginalized
and
some
are
powerful
enough
to
influence
the
policy
process
significantly.
What
is
clear
is
that
one
must
always
be
mindful
of
the
pressure
groups
that
could
potentially
derail
a
reform,
and
that
will
certainly
fight
against
each
other
in
an
attempt
to
monopolize
the
ability
to
frame
the
debate
and
contribute
to
agenda
setting.
5.1
Policy
Framework
Option:
Legalization
Legalization
is
the
most
radical
of
the
policy
options
discussed
in
this
paper,
and
also
the
least
likely
to
ever
be
implemented
in
the
United
States.
That
being
said
this
author
believes
it
is
worth
considering
as
an
ideal
type
that
can
be
compared
to
the
other
‘hybrid’
policy
reform
possibilities
that
will
be
subsequently
considered.
Legalization
entails
the
complete
elimination
of
prohibitions
against
a
certain
substance
or
substances.
For
example
one
United
States
Drug
Policy
67
could
consider
legalizing
a
certain
drug,
marijuana
for
instance,
or
all
currently
illicit
drugs.
This
policy
is
likely
to
have
the
opposition
of
most
of
the
aforementioned
stakeholder
groups,
but
there
are
many
benefits
of
a
legalization
policy,
even
from
the
perspectives
of
the
various
opponents
of
the
policy.
From
a
fiscal
perspective
legalization
would
be
the
most
beneficial
policy
because
the
widest
variety
of
drugs
would
be
available
to
the
public
and
could
therefore
be
taxed
and
regulated.
The
tax
dollars
used
to
fund
the
enforcement
of
prohibition
would
be
saved
and
revenue
could
be
raised
from
a
sin
tax
on
these
mind‐altering
substances,
assuming
the
tax
remains
reasonable
enough
to
prevent
the
emergence
of
a
black
market.
The
black
market
in
this
case
would
either
be
drastically
reduced
or
totally
eliminated,
which
benefits
the
whole
society.
One
could
use
the
current
examples
of
the
tobacco
or
alcohol
markets
as
evidence
of
the
lack
of
black
markets;
assuming
taxes
remained
reasonable
the
black
market
would
disappear
in
all
cases
perhaps
with
the
exception
of
those
seeking
particularly
potent
supplies
of
a
given
drug.
On
average
the
potency
of
drugs
would
remain
constant
or
slowly
fall
over
time
due
to
regulatory
controls,
and
due
to
the
elimination
of
the
trend
of
increasing
potency
under
a
prohibitionary
regime
as
discussed
above
as
a
general
effect
of
prohibition.
Again,
evidence
of
this
can
be
found
in
the
historical
analysis
of
what
happened
in
the
period
of
Alcohol
Prohibition.
The
elimination
of
the
black
market
would
be
perhaps
the
most
important
effect
of
drug
legalization,
which
would
have
national
and
international
implications.
The
first
effect
would
be
the
elimination
of
the
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
68
negative
external
effects
on
neighboring
countries.
This
would
especially
benefit
Mexico,
which
is
currently
in
a
life‐or‐death
struggle
against
drug
cartels,
and
the
Andean
nations,
which
have
economies
heavily
reliant
on
the
production
of
coca
products.
In
one
way
legalization
in
the
U.S.
would
hurt
local
farmers
in
some
areas
of
these
countries
by
reducing
the
price
they
could
get
for
their
crops,
but
legalization
would
also
greatly
improve
the
security
of
these
countries
by
integrating
production
and
transport
of
these
substances
into
the
existing
legal
framework.
The
black
market
within
the
U.S.
would
also
be
destroyed
by
legalization,
which
would
have
domestic
security
implications
as
well.
The
current
illegal
distribution
network
would
be
eliminated,
and
the
inner‐city
gangs
would
also
have
difficulty
maintaining
themselves.
It
is
possible
that
they
could
earn
enough
revenue
to
stay
in
existence
from
illegal
gambling
or
prostitution,
but
this
possibility
only
exists
because
of
other
prohibitions
that
could
be
eliminated
as
well.
The
incentives
to
commit
violence
would
disappear
as
the
entirety
of
the
drug
trade
would
now
fall
under
the
jurisdiction
of
the
legal
system
and
contracts
would
be
able
to
be
enforced
without
sending
in
strongmen.
Those
with
business
acumen
would
be
attracted
to
the
market
rather
than
those
willing
to
commit
violence
to
expand
or
maintain
their
distribution
monopolies
on
certain
territories.
The
final
effect
worth
mentioning
in
this
section
is
the
effect
on
public
health.
Clearly
drug
use
in
a
legalized
regime
would
increase,
especially
initially,
and
possibly
fall
over
a
period
of
decades
to
reach
a
new
equilibrium.
That
being
said
more
options
would
be
available
for
drug
users
to
receive
the
United
States
Drug
Policy
69
treatment
they
need
because
the
fear
of
incarceration
inherent
in
a
prohibitionary
regime
would
be
eliminated.
Due
to
legalization
drug
quality
would
improve
and
purity
would
stabilize,
as
people
would
be
able
to
rely
on
the
reputation
building
features
of
legal
market
transactions
to
regulate
distributers
who
are
looking
to
maintain
their
customers
by
supplying
a
consistent
product.
This
product
reliability
would
improve
public
health
over
time.
The
effect
of
legalization
on
the
spread
of
communicable,
especially
sexually
transmitted,
diseases
would
be
positive
as
addicts
would
be
able
to
carry
sterile
needles
without
the
fear
of
being
incarcerated
for
drug
paraphernalia
charges.
Additionally,
the
need
for
high‐risk
shooting
galleries
would
be
reduced,
as
the
criminality
of
their
activities
would
be
eliminated.
5.2
Policy
Framework
Option:
Decriminalization
Decriminalization
is
an
option
best
exemplified
by
the
Portuguese
implementation
discussed
in
section
3.2.
Under
a
decriminalization
regime
drug
possession
is
removed
from
the
realm
of
criminal
law
and
becomes
an
administrative
offense.
One
major
advantage
of
such
a
system
is
that
it
removes
the
social
stigma
associated
with
drug
use
by
removing
criminal
citations
from
the
public
records
of
individual
users.
The
destigmatization
caused
by
such
a
reform
is
likely
to
result
in
increased
demand
for
treatment
because
the
fear
of
arrest
is
eliminated
by
the
reform.
In
a
decriminalized
regime
the
state
can
still
incentivize
users
to
get
treatment
through
dissuasion
committees,
or
similar
constructions,
that
can
be
empowered
to
waive
fines
if
the
offender
agrees
to
attend
a
drug
treatment
program.
Additionally,
through
the
adoption
of
this
kind
of
policy
the
government
at
all
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
70
levels
can
save
money
on
enforcement,
which
can
be
redistributed
to
other
areas
like
treatment
or
simply
be
remitted
to
the
taxpayers,
and
police
can
again
focus
on
crimes
that
cause
damage
to
person
or
property.
One
advantage
of
decriminalization
over
legalizations
is
that
through
its
adoption
the
country
can
remain
within
the
framework
of
international
agreements
like
the
1971
Convention
on
Psychotropic
Substances
and
the
1988
United
Nations
Convention
against
Illicit
Traffic
in
Narcotic
Drugs
and
Psychotropic
Substances,
which
only
require
possession
of
drugs
for
personal
use
to
be
prohibited;
the
classification
of
the
offense
as
an
administrative
offense
rather
than
a
criminal
offense
satisfies
the
obligations
required
under
international
law.
Possession
with
intent
to
distribute,
drug
trafficking,
and
providing
drugs
to
children
and
mentally
ill
remain
criminal
acts
in
a
decriminalization
regime,
which
also
satisfies
international
obligations.
A
disadvantage
of
decriminalization
compared
to
legalization
is
that
the
effect
on
the
international
and
domestic
black
markets
is
uncertain.
In
Portugal
the
total
consumption
of
drugs
across
all
demographic
groups
has
fallen,
which
would
seem
to
imply
that
demand
is
down
and
trafficking
should
have
diminished
as
a
result.
One
thing
that
remains
unclear
though,
is
how
Portugal
is
being
used
now
as
a
distribution
point
for
other
countries.
It
could
be
that
usage
is
down
but
trafficking
activities
are
up,
as
Portugal
has
become
an
international
hub
of
the
drug
trade,
unfortunately
no
relevant
information
on
this
subject
exists.
United
States
Drug
Policy
71
5.3
Policy
Framework
Option:
Depenalization
Depenalization
is
a
policy
that
maintains
the
illegality
of
drug
offenses
including
possession
for
personal
use,
and
responds
to
these
offenses
with
criminal
sanctions.
However,
possession
for
personal
consumption
would
remain
a
crime
that
is
punished
only
through
the
imposition
of
a
fine
and
a
criminal
record
indicating
the
offense.
This
policy,
while
the
least
dramatic
of
the
three
discussed
in
this
section,
still
provides
significant
advantages
over
the
current
system.
The
biggest
of
these
advantages
is
the
cost
savings
associated
with
reduced
prison
populations
and
reduced
judicial
costs.
This
savings
could
be
reallocated
or
passed
on
to
the
taxpayer.
If
reallocated,
one
can
certainly
imagine
the
efficacy
of
redistributing
the
funds
to
treatment
programs,
which
have
been
proven
to
reduce
usage
and
addiction
to
a
far
greater
degree
than
prison
terms.
Another
advantage
of
depenalization
that
should
not
be
discounted
is
that
this
policy
remains
consistent
with
international
obligations
designed
to
reduce
trafficking.
6.
Policy
Recommendation
In
the
previous
section
we
discussed
possible
policy
frameworks
for
reforming
U.S.
drug
policy,
and
in
this
section
we
will
elaborate
by
providing
a
concrete
policy
recommendation.
To
reiterate,
in
the
U.S.
different
policy
levels
influence
the
total
drug
policy
of
the
country;
these
level
are
federal,
state
and
local.
The
federal
policy,
as
presently
articulated
by
the
ONDCP,
is
the
most
influential
as
it
serves
to
coordinate
the
policies
on
all
three
levels.
The
problem
with
this
is
that,
as
we
have
seen,
the
state
and
local
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
72
governments
have
been
encapsulated
within
the
failing
strategy
of
the
federal
government,
the
laws
of
which
supersede
those
of
the
state
and
local
governments.
In
the
past,
as
in
the
case
of
the
California
marijuana
dispensaries,
federal
officials
have
arrested
individuals
in
violation
of
federal
drug
laws
in
states
where
those
activities
were
legal.
This
policy
has
undermined
one
of
federalism’s
key
advantages,
that
power
be
dispersed
geographically
so
that
the
various
states
or
regional
areas
can
serve
as
a
kind
of
policy
laboratory.
Therefore
one
recommendation
is
the
decriminalization
of
marijuana
at
the
federal
level,
which
would
eliminate
the
danger
of
federal
field
operatives
from
undermining
central
objectives
by
“going
local”
and
remove
barriers
that
presently
prevent
states
from
adopting
a
more
entrepreneurial
policy.229
Decriminalization
would
allow
the
federal
government
to
raise
revenue
from
individuals
found
to
be
in
possession
of
marijuana,
however,
the
policy
should
allow
the
federal
enforcement
officials
to
impose
these
fines
only
in
addition
to
other
federal
crime
enforcement.
Decriminalization
would
also
allow
states
to
act
as
policy
laboratories
that,
over
time,
will
be
able
to
find
policy
approaches
that
work
well,
while
not
overturning
the
convictions
of
the
more
conservative
states
that
wish
to
maintain
prohibition.
Americans
have
seen
California
at
the
forefront
of
drug
policy
since
1996;
altering
federal
policy
would
encourage
other
states
to
adopt
a
more
experimental
approach
to
drug
policy,
in
which
policies
can
be
adopted,
evaluated,
and
changed
if
found
to
be
ineffective.
In
addition,
the
financial
costs
of
prohibition
would
shift
to
the
taxpayers
in
those
states
that
229
Andrew
B.
Whitford,
“Decentralized
Policy
Implementation,”
Political
Research
Quarterly
60,
no.
1
(2007):
17
United
States
Drug
Policy
73
wished
to
maintain
that
policy,
which
would
serve
to
readjust
incentives.
States
would
also
be
encouraged
by
this
policy
change
to
experiment
with
different
approaches
to
dealing
with
the
drug
problem
without
the
fear
that
the
federal
government
will
overturn
their
laws
whenever
they
feel
it
is
justified.
The
reason
for
only
recommending
marijuana
decriminalization
is
the
unlikelihood
of
passage
of
a
federal
legalization
for
all
drugs,
which
would
be
more
likely
to
reduce
the
negative
externalities
associated
with
prohibition
even
further
while
allowing
states
to
have
their
own
policies.
In
addition,
cannabis
should
be
targeted
because
it
is
the
world’s
top
illegal
drug
in
terms
of
quantity
produced
and
number
of
users,
and,
in
terms
of
quantity
seized,
between
the
United
States
and
Mexico
59%
of
the
total
cannabis
seized
comes
from
these
two
countries.230
With
any
policy
recommendation
one
must
consider
possible
methods
for
measuring
success
or
failure.
I
recommend
a
10‐year
trial
policy
period,
or
a
federal
law
that
would
have
a
10‐year
sunset
provision.
The
reason
for
this
is
to
force
an
evaluation
period
that
would
serve
to
refute
the
policy,
justify
the
policy,
or
justify
an
expansion
of
the
policy
to
other
drugs
if
there
was
enough
success
to
justify
it.
One
current
method
for
gathering
data
on
drug
use
is
through
surveys
like
the
Monitoring
the
Future,
and
the
National
Household
Survey
on
Drug
Abuse,
which
should
be
continued
after
the
implementation
of
the
new
policy,
which
is
likely
even
though
there
are
questions
about
reporting
bias
because
they
are
230
Anonymous,
2008
World
Drug
Report,
102
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
74
administered
by
private
organizations.231
The
ONDCP
should
be
the
organization
responsible
for
the
evaluation
of
the
policy,
which
is
required
in
response
to
the
proposed
sunset
provision.
However,
in
order
to
ensure
that
the
evaluation
is
unbiased
and
not
subject
to
political
pressure,
the
ONDCP
should
be
removed
from
the
executive
branch.
Additionally,
its
mission
should
be
changed
from
strong
advocacy
of
the
drug
war
to
conducting
an
analysis
of
policy
that
apolitically
advocates
strategies
that
would
improve
the
situations
of
all
segments
of
society.
As
an
independent
governmental
body
it
would
be
able
to
fulfill
this
goal;
as
an
executive
organ
it
can
not.
The
aforementioned
stakeholders
are
likely
to
influence
the
agenda
setting
and
policy
formulation
parts
of
the
policy
cycle
more
than
the
implementation
or
evaluation
parts;
these
groups
realize
this
and
are
likely
to
make
their
stand
during
these
phases.
While
the
enforcement
stakeholders
are
likely
are
likely
to
oppose
the
proposed
policy,
it
is
clear
that
it
is
possible
to
overcome
this
group’s
pressure
as
evidenced
by
the
reform
in
California,
Oregon
and
Massachusetts.
The
proposed
policy
is
unlikely
to
draw
as
much
resistance
from
this
group
as
full
scale
liberalization,
but
their
power
to
derail
a
reform
should
not
be
underestimated.
The
proposal
is
likely
to
garner
significant,
albeit
incomplete,
support
from
liberalization
advocated
divided
along
the
spectrum
of
possible
liberalization
reforms.
To
clarify,
the
proposed
policy
is
likely
to
go
too
far
to
please
some,
and
not
go
far
enough
to
please
others,
as
it
is
a
relatively
moderate
reform
considering
liberalization
as
the
point
of
departure.
As
this
group
is
also
politically
dispersed
it
is
231
Denise
B.
Kandel,
“The
Social
Demography
of
Drug
Use,”
The
Milbank
Quarterly
69,
no.
3
(1991):
317.
United
States
Drug
Policy
75
unlikely
that
it
will,
without
external
support,
be
able
to
significantly
engage
in
a
concerted
effort
to
influence
either
the
agenda
setting
or
policy
formulation
phases.
The
pharmacological
stakeholder
is
well
funded
and
able
to
influence
both
agenda
setting
and
policy
formulation,
but
its
disadvantage
is
that
it
is
known
to
be
a
biased
lobby
group.
This
fact
could
help
to
diminish
the
influence
this
group
has
if
such
a
large
scale
and
far
reaching
reform
is
considered.
It
is
likely
to
oppose
the
proposal
due
to
the
fact
that
the
reform
would
introduce
a
modicum
of
competition
against
the
products
of
this
stakeholder.
Finally,
the
Christian
Right,
or
moralist,
stakeholder
group
would
no
doubt
oppose
the
proposal
on
moral
grounds.
The
group
represents
a
powerful
wing
of
the
Republican
Party
that
is
able
to
influence
the
platform
of
that
party.
Its
influence
may
be
somewhat
confounded
by
the
free
market
proponents
within
the
same
party,
but
the
group
still
represents
a
threat
to
the
proposed
policy.
At
present
count
we
have
listed
several
stakeholders
who
would
oppose
the
policy
proposal,
and
only
one
politically
dispersed
group
that
would
support
it.
It
is
evident
that
in
order
for
the
proposal
to
become
a
reality
much
public
support
would
be
necessary,
and
it
seems
likely
that
the
Obama
administration
would
have
to
be
at
least
neutral.
As
public
support
has
been
steadily
increasing
for
some
time
it
seems
possible
for
a
degree
of
pressure
to
be
applied
by
this
group,
and
the
question
of
the
administration’s
support
remains
unanswered.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
76
Conclusion
Drug
policy
is
a
difficult
policy
area
because
there
are
a
variety
of
interests
that
need
to
be
balanced
while
ensuring
that
the
resulting
policy
is
effective
at
reducing
harm
caused
by
the
use
of
drugs.
There
is
much
demagoguery
surrounding
the
issue
from
all
sides,
and
through
time
concern
for
the
usage
has
waxed
and
waned
hinging
on
the
rhetoric
of
these
demagogues.
In
the
last
10‐15
years
public
opinion
has
shifted
from
one
of
fierce
opposition
to
usage,
to
one
that
recognizes
the
possible
medical
use
of
marijuana
and
is
more
compassionate
towards
drug
addicts
in
general
as
addiction
has
increasingly
been
recognized
as
a
legitimate
disease,
much
like
alcoholism
has
been
recognized.
While
it
is
clear
that
Obama
is
not
willing
to
legalize
currently
illicit
substances,
his
more
liberal
attitude
toward
drug
policy
combined
with
increasingly
tolerant
public
opinion
may
be
the
best
opportunity
for
substantial
reform
in
recent
history,
and
for
the
foreseeable
future.
United
States
Drug
Policy
77
Bibliography
Acosta,
Jim,
and
Kristi
Keck,
“White
House
Tries
to
Combat
Drug
Demand
with
Rehab,”
CNN
(Apr.
18,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://edition.cnn.com/2009/POLITICS/04/18/obama.drug.war/index.html
Anonymous,
“2008
World
Drug
Report,”
United
Nations
Office
on
Drugs
and
Crime
(2008),
editied
by
Sandeep
Chawlap:
available
from
www.unodc.org/documents/wdr/...2008/WDR_2008_eng_web.pdf
Anonymous.
“72%
Want
Obama
to
End
DEA
Raids,”
Obamawerds
(Feb
4,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009])
available
from
http://obamawerds.com/articles/viewArticle/72_want_Obama_to_end_DEA_raids
Anonymous.
“California
Medical
Marijuana
Information,”
U.S.
Drug
Enforcement
Agency
[cited
10
Jul.
2009]:
available
from
http://www.medbd.ca.gov/medical_marijuana.html
Anonymous.
“Barney
Frank
Files
Bill
to
Decriminalize
Pot,”
wbztv
(Jun.
19
2009
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://wbztv.com/local/marijuana.federal.penalty.2.1052437.html
Anonymous.
“Drug
Tax
Stamp,”
Kansas
Department
of
Revenue
(2009
[cited
15
Jul.
2009])
available
from
http://www.ksrevenue.org/perstaxtypesdrug.htm
Anonymous,
“Drug
Use
Trends,”
Office
of
National
Drug
Control
Policy
(October
2002
[cited
16
Jul.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.whitehousedrugpolicy.gov/publications/factsht/druguse/
Anonymous.
“Editorial:
Front
Line:
Mexico,”
The
Philadelphia
Inquirer
(Mar.
1,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.philly.com/inquirer/currents/20090301_Editorial__Front_Line__Mexico.html?re ferrer=digg.
Anonymous.
“Ex‐presidents
of
Latin
America
Urge
Legal
Marijuana,”
CNN
(Feb.
11,
2009
[23
Feb.
2009]):
available
from
http://edition.cnn.com/2009/WORLD/americas/02/11/brazil.marijuana/index.html
Anonymous.
“Medical
Marijuana,”
The
Medical
Board
of
California
(May
7,
2004
[cited
10
Jul.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.medbd.ca.gov/medical_marijuana.html
Anonymous,
“The
Case
for
Legalization,”
The
Economist
Print
Edition
(Jul.
26,
2001
[cited
25
May
2009])
Armentano,
Paul.
“ABC
News:
Public
Support
for
Pot
Legalization
Has
Never
Been
Higher!,”
NORML
(Apr.
30,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://blog.norml.org/2009/04/30/abc‐news‐publics‐support‐for‐pot‐legalization‐has‐ never‐been‐higher/
Balko,
Radley.
“SWAT
Gone
Wild
in
Maryland,”
Reason
Online
(Jul.
13,
2009
[cited
16
Jul.
2009]):
available
at
http://www.reason.com/news/show/134734.html
Barr,
Kellie
E.
M.,
Michael
P.
Farrell,
Grace
M.
Barnes,
John
W.
Welte,
“Race,
Class,
and
Gender
Differences
in
Substance
Abuse:
Evidence
of
Middle‐Class/Underclass
Polarization
Among
Blacks,”
Social
Problems
40,
no.
3
(1993):
321.
Beckett,
Katherine,
Kris
Nyrop,
Lori
Pfingst,
Melissa
Bowen,
“Drug
Use,
Drug
Possession
Arrests,
and
the
Question
of
Race:
Lessons
from
Seattle,”
Social
Problems
52,
no.
3
(2005):
434.
Beckett,
Katherine.
“Setting
the
Public
Agenda:
“Street
Crime”
and
Drug
Use
in
American
Politics,”
Social
Problems
41,
no.
3
(1994):
425.
Benoit,
Ellen.
“Not
Just
a
Matter
of
Criminal
Justice:
States,
Institutions,
and
North
American
Drug
Policy,”
Sociological
Forum
18,
no.
2
(2003):
285.
Birkey,
Andy.
“Medical
Marijuana
Bill
Advances
in
Senate
with
Moving
Testimony,”
Minnesota
Independent
(Feb.
12,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://minnesotaindependent.com/26340/medical‐marijuana‐bill‐advances‐in‐senate‐with‐ moving‐testimony
Burke,
Anna
Celeste.
“Between
Entitlement
and
Control:
Dimensions
of
U.S.
Drug
Policy,”
The
Social
Service
Review
66,
no.
4
(1992):
573.
Calmes,
Jackie.
“Obama
Plans
Major
Shifts
in
Spending,”
New
York
Times
(Feb.
26,
2009
[cited
8
Jul.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/02/27/us/politics/27web‐ budget.html
Caulkins,
Jonathan
P.
“Zero‐Tolerance
Policies:
Do
They
Inhibit
of
Stimulate
Illicit
Drug
Consumption,”
Management
Science
39,
no.
4
(1993):
46.
Collins,
Larry.
“Holland’s
Half‐Baked
Drug
Experiment,”
Foreign
Affairs
78,
no.
3
(1999):
83.
Crary,
David.
“Momentum
Builds
for
Broad
Debate
on
Legalizing
Pot,”
The
Associated
Press
(Jun.
15
2009
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.google.com/hostednews/ap/article/ALeqM5i_7aIzdypWz2A‐ dtVHeJ8VZ7vLFAD98R92S80
DeSimone,
Jeff.
“Illegal
Drug
Use
and
Employment,”
Journal
of
Labor
Economics
20,
no.
4
(2002):
970.
Diaz‐Duran,
Constantino.
“America
Should
Decriminalize
Drugs,”
The
Daily
Beast
(Apr.
19,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.thedailybeast.com/blogs‐and‐ stories/2009‐04‐19/drug‐war‐lessons‐from‐colombia/
Edwards,
David
and
Stephen
C.
Webster.
“Arizona
AG:
Pot
Legalization
Could
Prevent
Border
Violence,”
The
Raw
Story
(Feb.
27,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://rawstory.com/news/2008/Arizona_AG_Pot_legalization_could_prevent_0227.html
Egelko,
Bob.
“U.S.
to
Yield
Marijuana
Jurisdiction
to
States,”
San
Francisco
Chronicle
(Feb
27,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.sfgate.com/cgi‐ bin/article.cgi?file=/c/a/2009/02/27/MN2016651R.DTL
Elfrink,
Tim.
“Black‐Market
Cigarettes:
Miami’s
New
Vice,”
Miama
New
Times
(Jun.
30,
2009
[cited
16
Jul.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.miaminewtimes.com/2009‐07‐ 02/news/black‐market‐cigarettes‐miami‐s‐new‐vice
Fields,
Gary.
“White
House
Czar
Calls
for
End
to
‘War
on
Drugs’,”
Wall
Street
Journal
(May
14,
2009
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB124225891527617397.html?
Greenwald,
Glenn.
“Drug
Decriminalization
in
Portugal:
Lessons
for
Creating
Fair
and
Successful
Drug
Policies,”
Cato
Institute,
10.
United
States
Drug
Policy
79
Goldacre,
Ben.
“Cocaine
Study
That
Got
Up
the
Nose
of
the
US,”
The
Guardian
(Jun.
13
2009
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.guardian.co.uk/commentisfree/2009/jun/13/bad‐science‐cocaine‐study
Grim,
Ryan.
“Supreme
Court
Hands
Medical
Marijuana
Major
Victory,”
The
Huffington
Post
(May
18,
2009
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
http://www.huffingtonpost.com/2009/05/18/supreme‐court‐hands‐medic_n_204681.html
Henry,
Ray.
“RI
Becomes
3rd
State
Allowing
Marijuana
Stores,”
The
Boston
Globe
(Jun.
16
2009
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.boston.com/news/local/rhode_island/articles/2009/06/16/ri_becomes_3rd_st ate_allowing_marijuana_stores_1245192510/
Jacobs,
Edward
A.
“Marijuana
and
Adolescents,”
The
Institute
on
Global
Drug
Policy
[cited
on
25
Jun.
2009]:
available
from
http://www.globaldrugpolicy.org/1/1/3.php
1
Robert
L.
DuPont,
“Barack
Obama
on
Medical
Marijuana,”
The
Institute
on
Global
Drug
Policy
[cited
25
Jun.
2009]:
available
from
http://www.globaldrugpolicy.org/3/1/commentary.php
Joseph,
Janice,
and
Patricia
G.
Pearson,
“Black
Youths
and
Illegal
Drugs,”
Journal
of
Black
Studies
32,
no.
4
(2002):
431.
Kandel,
Denise
B.
“The
Social
Demography
of
Drug
Use,”
The
Milbank
Quarterly
69,
no.
3
(1991).
Kerlikowske,
Gil.
Domestic
Policy
Subcommittee
Oversight
and
Government
Reform
Committee.
“Testimony
Of
Gil
Kerlikowske,
National
Drug
Control
Policy
Director
ONDCP's
Fiscal
Year
2010
National
Drug
Control
Budget
and
the
Priorities,
Objectives,
and
Policies
of
the
Office
of
National
Drug
Control
Policy
under
the
New
Administration.”
Available
from
www.whitehousedrugpolicy.gov/news/testimony09/051909_dpc_subcommittee.pdf
Klein,
Dorie,
Robin
E.
Miller,
Amanda
Noble,
and
Richard
Speiglman.
“Incorporating
a
Public
Health
Approach
in
Drug
Law:
Lessons
from
Local
Expansion
of
Treatment
Capacity
and
Access
under
California’s
Proposition
36,”
The
Milbank
Quarterly
82,
no.
4
(2004).
Klein,
Joe.
“Why
Legalizing
Marijuana
Makes
Sense,”
Time
Magazine
(Apr.
2,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.time.com/time/nation/article/0,8599,1889021,00.html?iid=digg_share
Konrad,
Kai
A.
“Drug
Policy
and
Federalism,”
Public
Choice
80,
no.
1/2
(1994):
57.
Krause,
Nancy.
“RI
Senate
Approves
Marijuana
Stores,”
WPRI
(Jun
10,
2009
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.wpri.com/dpp/news/local_news/local_wpri_providence_senate_passes_medical _marijuana_compassion_center_bill_20090609_nek
Leuw,
Ed.
“Drugs
and
Drug
Policy
in
the
Netherlands,”
Crime
and
Justice
14,
no.
47
(1991):
230.
Loo,
Mirjam
van
het,
Ineke
van
Beusekom,
James
P.
Kahan,
“Decriminalization
of
Drug
Use
in
Portugal:
The
Development
of
a
Policy,”
Annals
of
the
American
Academy
of
Political
and
Social
Science
582,
no.
14
(2002):
50.
Miron,
Jeffrey
A.
and
Jeffrey
Zwiebel.
“Alcohol
Consumption
During
Prohibition,”
The
American
Economic
Review
81,
no.
2
(1991):
242.
Miron,
Jeffrey
A.
and
Jeffrey
Zwiebel.
“The
Economic
Case
Against
Drug
Prohibition,”
The
Journal
of
Economic
Perspectives
9,
no.
4
(1995):
176.
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
80
Miron,
Jeffrey
A.
“The
Effect
of
Drug
Prohibition
on
Drug
Prices:
Evidence
from
the
Markets
for
Cocaine
and
Heroin,”
The
Review
of
Economics
and
Statistics
85,
no.
3
(2003):
522.
Mohammed,
Arshad.
“U.S.
to
Blame
for
Much
of
Mexico
Violence:
Clinton,”
Reuters
(Mar.
25,
2009
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.reuters.com/article/topNews/idUSTRE52O5RF20090325?feedType=R%20SS& feedName=topNews&rpc=22&sp=true.
Moore,
Solomon.
“Tougher
Border
Can’t
Stop
Mexican
Marijuana
Cartels,”
New
York
Times
(Feb.
1,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/02/02/us/02pot.html?ex=1391317200&en=bd77410a2ec4 8dbd&ei=5124&partner=digg&exprod=digg
Nadelmann,
Ethan
A.
“Commonsense
Drug
Policy,”
Foreign
Affairs
77,
no.
1
(1998):
117.
Nadelmann,
Ethan
A.
“U.S.
Drug
Policy:
A
Bad
Export,”
Foreign
Policy
70,
no.
25
(1988):
86.
O'Grady,
Mary
Anastasia.
“A
Stimulus
Plan
for
Mexican
Gangsters,”
The
Wall
Street
Journal
(Mar.
2,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB123595140575504953.html
Perl,
Raphael
Francis.
“Congress,
International
Narcotics
Policy,
and
the
Anti‐Drug
Abuse
Act
of
1988,”
Journal
of
Interamerican
Studies
and
World
Affairs
30,
no.
2/3
(1988):
34.
Perl,
Raphael
Francis.
“United
States
International
Drug
Policy:
Recent
Developments
and
Issues,”
Journal
of
Interamerican
Studies
and
World
Affairs
32,
no.
4
(1990):
123.
Pitts,
Leonard
Jr.
“Begin
Discussion
on
Legalizing
Drugs,”
Miami
Herald
(Mar.
31,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.miamiherald.com/living/columnists/leonard‐pitts/story/978041.html
Recio,
Gabriela.
“Drugs
and
Alcohol:
US
Prohibition
and
the
Origins
of
the
Drug
Trade
in
Mexico,”
Journal
of
Latin
American
Studies
34,
no.
3
(2002):
27.
Richardson,
John
H.
“He’s
Not
High:
Inside
Barney
Frank's
Plan
to
Legalize
Marijuana,”
Esquire
Magazine
(Jul.
14,
2009
[cited
16
Jul.
2009]):
available
at
http://www.esquire.com/the‐side/richardson‐report/new‐marijuana‐laws‐ 071309?src=digg
Robinson,
Matthew
B.
and
Renee
G.
Scherlen.
Lies,
Damned
Lies,
and
Drug
War
Statistics
(Albany:
State
University
of
New
York
Press,
2007),
12.
Rutten,
Tim.
“The
War
We
Gave
Mexico,”
Los
Angeles
Times
(Feb.
28,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009])
available
from
http://www.latimes.com/news/opinion/sunday/commentary/la‐oe‐ rutten28‐2009feb28,0,2564151.column
Sabet,
Kevin
A.
“The
Price
of
Legalizing
Pot
is
too
High,”
Los
Angeles
Times
(Jun.
7,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.latimes.com/news/la‐oe‐sabet7‐ 2009jun07,0,5717495.story?track=rss
San
Pedro,
Emilio.
“U.S.
Ready
to
Aid
Mexico
Drug
Fight,”
BBC
(Mar.
2,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/americas/7918101.stm
Schneider,
Cathy
Lisa.
“Racism,
Drug
Policy,
and
AIDS,”
Political
Science
Quarterly
113,
no.
3
(1998):
434.
United
States
Drug
Policy
81
Stateman,
Alison.
“In
California
Marijuana
Truce,
a
Legal
Grey
Area,”
Time
Magazine
(Mar.
29,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.time.com/time/nation/article/0,8599,1888172,00.html?iid=digg_share
Stossel,
John.
“Prohibition
Spawns
Drug
Violence,”
Creators
Syndicate
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]:
available
from
http://www.creators.com/opinion/john‐stossel/prohibition‐spawns‐drug‐ violence.html
Szalavitz,
Maia.
“Drugs
in
Portugal:
Did
Decriminalization
Work?,”
Time
Magazine
(Apr.
26,
2009
[cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.time.com/time/health/article/0,8599,1893946,00.html?xid=rss‐topstories
Thornton,
Mark.
The
Economics
of
Prohibition
(Salt
Lake
City:
University
of
Utah
Press,
1991),
3.
Vick,
Karl.
“In
Calif.,
Medical
Marijuana
Laws
Are
Moving
Pot
Into
the
Mainstream,”
Washington
Post
(Apr.
12,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp‐ dyn/content/article/2009/04/11/AR2009041100767.html?referrer=digg
Watson,
Julie.
“It’s
Police
vs.
Police
in
Mexican
Drug
War,”
The
Star
(Jun.
10,
2009
{cited
24
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.thestar.com/news/world/article/648303
Whitford,
Andrew
B.
“Decentralized
Policy
Implementation,”
Political
Research
Quarterly
60,
no.
1
(2007).
Wooldridge,
Frosty.
“Marijuana
Prohibition
and
Public
Safety,”
The
Examiner
(Mar.
2,
2009
[cited
23
Jun.
2009]):
available
from
http://www.examiner.com/x‐3515‐Denver‐Political‐ Issues‐Examiner~y2009m3d2‐Marijuana‐prohibition‐and‐public‐safety
Developing
a
Rational
Framework
82
Erklärung
gemäß
§
25
Abs.
1
der
Prüfungs‐
und
Studienordnung
des
weiterbildenden
Studiums
„Public
Policy"
an
der
Universität
Erfurt.
Ich
versichere,
dass
ich
die
vorgelegte
Arbeit
selbstständig
und
ohne
unerlaubte
Hilfe
Dritter
angefertigt
habe.
Alle
Stellen,
die
ich
wörtlich
oder
annähernd
wörtlich
aus
Veröffentlichungen
jeglicher
Art
entnommen
habe,
sind
als
solche
kenntlich
gemacht.
Ich
habe
mich
keiner
anderen
als
der
an‐ gegebenen
Literatur
oder
sonstiger
Hilfsmittel
bedient.
Diese
Arbeit
hat
weder
in
gleicher
noch
in
ähnlicher
Form
einer
anderen
Prüfungsbehörde
im
In‐
oder
Ausland
vorgelegen.
I
affirm
that
the
work
I
have
submitted
was
done
independently
and
without
unauthorized
assistance
from
third
parties.
All
parts
which
I
took
wordfor word
or
nearly
wordforword
from
any
sort
of
publication
are
recognizable
as
such,
l
did
not
use
any
means
or
resources
other
than
the
literature
I
have
quoted.
This
work
was
not
submitted
in
this
or
any
similar
form
to
an
examination
committee
in
or
outside
of
Germany.
Erfurt,
_17.07.2009
Datum
/
Date
_______________________
Unterschrift
/
Signature
______Alec_S._Johnston_____
Name
(Blockschrift
/
block
letters)
United
States
Drug
Policy
83