Econ 325

  • November 2019
  • PDF

This document was uploaded by user and they confirmed that they have the permission to share it. If you are author or own the copyright of this book, please report to us by using this DMCA report form. Report DMCA


Overview

Download & View Econ 325 as PDF for free.

More details

  • Words: 9,388
  • Pages: 36
Opalo Kennedy Opalo Econ 325: Economies of Developing Countries1. Prof. Una Osili

Economic Integration and Monetary Unions in Africa: Hurdles and Possibilities Introduction: Sub-Saharan Africa2 (hereafter Africa) continues to lag behind other regions of the world in terms of economic growth and development. Over the years, a lot of ink has been spilled in trying to explain this fact. Explanations put forward by various scholars, to mention a few, have included the region’s inappropriate development strategies that are dependent on inward-looking policies meant to capture rents rather than foster growth (Thomson and Thomson, 2000; Dollar, 1992; Cleaver, 1985); external obstacles to trade, especially with regard to policy choices of the Global North , such as the much maligned agricultural policies of the European Union and the United States of America (Amjadi et al., 1996); undemocratic governance that has produced kleptocratic dictators and caused civil strife which has diverted valuable resources from the development agenda to war efforts (Collier, 2007; Masson and Patillo, 2005); bad geography (rugged terrain and lack of access to the sea) that renders transport costs, a vital component of trade, prohibitively high (Sachs, 1998); the legacy of colonialism that created unsuitable

1

This paper was originally presented as a fifteen page paper in a class on the economies of developing countries. I have since had to incorporate new material and expand some of the arguments presented for the purposes of submitting it as a sample paper. 2 Sub-Saharan Africa comprises of countries on the continent of Africa South of the Sahara desert. This grouping excludes countries from North Africa like Morocco, Tunisia, Libya, Egypt and Algeria.

1

Opalo path-dependencies with regard to trade and institutional structures (Nunn, 2007; Young, 2004); or simply bad leadership3 (Achebe, 1985). Naturally, none of the explanations provided can singly explain Africa’s underdevelopment. Each only provides a partial answer as to why the region has lagged behind others like the Pacific Rim4 which took a meteoric rise towards becoming developed economies in the 1980s. Most, if not all, of the existing explanations for Africa’s underdevelopment have been state-centric. They have mostly implied that solutions lie within the boundaries of the individual countries, if only these countries’ governments can get their act together. While this might be true, there is a need to look for alternative solutions that are not state-centric, especially in light of the increasing rate of globalization. The increasing interconnectedness of nations through commerce, not just in the regions with developed economies, but even in Africa necessitates the search for solutions that look beyond national borders. It is for this reason that this paper provides an analysis of two complementary approaches to tackling Africa’s underdevelopment: monetary unions and economic integration in the different regions of the continent. Through a survey of the existing literature on economic integration and monetary unions, this paper explores the viability of these two approaches in the African situation in an attempt to spur economic growth.

3

Chinua Achebe’s famous 1985 book criticized the Nigerian political leadership. The same criticism can be leveled against other leaders on the continent of Africa. 4 It is interesting to note that when most African states gained their independence from Western Europe in the 1960s, some African countries were at the same level of economic development as many East Asian countries. To illustrate this point, in 1975 the GDP in Africa and Asia was US $ 713 and US $ 309 respectively. In 2004, these figures were US $ 1,842 and US $ 5,331 respectively. This fact is important in dispelling the argument that Asia had a head-start in the development trajectory. See the Japan Bank for International Cooperation Institute paper on “Experience in Infrastructure Construction in East Asia and Sub-Saharan Africa:Implications for Infrastructure Aid in Africa.” (2008).

2

Opalo Hereafter, this paper is divided into four sections. The first section provides a survey of the conditions in Africa that make it a particularly suitable region for implementing monetary unions and economic integration. The second section looks at economic integration, focusing on the existing literature on the subject, economic theory and how these apply to the African condition. The third section looks at monetary unions, again focusing on the existing literature and economic theory behind it and how it applies to Africa. The fourth section illuminates on some of the challenges that might hinder successful implementation of the ideas put forth in this paper. Lastly the conclusion recapitulates the main points presented in this paper and offers suggestions for further research in this area of Development Economics.

Background: Most African states have neither been strong militarily nor had isolationist nationalism. This can be attributed to the processes that created them and their existing eclectic ethnic mix. Unlike older Westphalian5 nation-states, many of these countries did not have to fight for and to maintain their territories since their borders were arbitrarily drawn by 19th century European powers6. The result was that these states did not have the incentives to promote economic activities that generated revenue or foster institutions that would sustain them as independent nation-states as was the case with states founded through wars of conquest (Tilly, 1990). This guarantee of territorial integrity after independence, later cemented by the current international regime may explain why most African states lack the ability to project power throughout all of their territories (Herbst, 2000). The Delta region in Nigeria,

5

This is a reference to the treaty of Westphalia (in actual sense the treaties of Osnabruck and Muster) of 1648 that is credited by most Political Scientists as having marked the beginning of the nation state as we know it – with clearly defined borders and legally unchallengeable sovereignty. 6 The partitioning of Africa took place in 1884-85 in Berlin, Germany in an attempt to peacefully divide territories in Africa among the imperial European powers at the time.

3

Opalo the Eastern provinces of the Democratic Republic of Congo, Eastern Chad, among others, all serve to confirm this theory. Ethnic diversity has also been a cause of the weakness of African states. First exploited by colonizers to divide and rule their colonies, ethnicity has since then been used by post-independence leaders to antagonize different regions of the same countries (Apollos, 2001). In light of these factors, it is evident that, historically, Africa lacks a brand of nationalism that would jeopardize attempts to institute economic integration and monetary unions across the continent, especially in the case where such integration did not affect the political power dynamics of participating countries. It may seem impracticable to call for economic and monetary union on a continent that is largely devoid of modern communication and transportation infrastructure vital aspects of economic growth and development. For instance, Africa as a region has the lowest landline telephone density in the world (Jerome, 1999). The continent has witnessed marked under-investment and mismanagement of its road, rail and port systems over the past few decades (Pedersen, 2001). Adding to Africa’s transportation woes is the fact that most of the rivers that run through the continent are not navigable due to rapids and waterfalls. But this is not the entire picture. The same Pedersen paper notes that there is a surprisingly high private interest in investing in railways and other transport infrastructure to facilitate the existing minimal intra-African trade. Pedersen also points out the fact that there is increasing regionalization of the continent around hub-ports and hub airports – in Nairobi, Abidjan and Johannesburg – which can be seen as pointers to the idea of regional economies around certain growth poles. In addition, free market policies adopted by a few countries in the 1990s have gone a long way in bringing much needed efficiency and expansion in Africa’s ports, in addition to reducing corruption 4

Opalo (Pedersen, 2001). Africa’s lack of robust infrastructure may even prove to be a plus. Economic and monetary integration will inevitably necessitate the construction of new transport and communication links. The non-existence of such links may prove advantageous in that it will help reduce switching costs and associated losses. The above arguments highlight the viability of economic and monetary integration in Africa. But perhaps a better case for this approach to development on the continent can be made using the population argument. In his famous book, Guns, Germs and Steel, Jared Diamond cited Africa’s low population density as a reason behind the continent's failure evolve nation-states with hard borders and lasting Weberian rational-legal institutions comparable to those that developed in regions with higher population densities (Diamond, 1997). Other scholars have cited this same reason for Africa’s failure to be part of the green revolution that spurred economic growth in more densely populated Asia (Johnson et al., 2003). Relating population density to innovation in agriculture, Boserup found that, high population densities are highly correlated with more intensive forms of farming – a case of necessity being the mother of invention. Her work also illustrated that a high population density stimulated European development of “special handicrafts and manufactured goods” (Boserup, 1981).Yet another advantage of a high population density is the simple fact that two heads are better than one. A bigger population is more diverse and thus, due to competition and shear numbers, has a higher probability of producing individuals with innovative ideas (Kremer, 1993).

5

Opalo Figure (i)

Source: Ray, Debraj: Population growth and economic development. Looking at figure 1 and assuming that the rate of population growth is consistent with this graph and diminishes over time, as the population grows so will the rate of technical innovation and income – as suggested by Kremer and Boserup. This results in a long-run situation where technological progress outpaces population growth leading to an increase in per capita income (Debraj, 1998). This analysis seems to fit the African condition. This vast continent is sparsely populated with millions who, able to own small pieces of land, eke out a living through subsistence agriculture. 6

Opalo The abundance of land in Africa obviates the need for intensive agricultural production and limits technological progress. The other problem related to low population densities is a lack of sufficient markets to support local industries. So in the African case, not only do industries not emerge because of a lack of innovation – a la Kremer – but also due to a lack of large-enough markets to support these industries. The demographic problem discussed here can be tackled by opening up Africa’s borders – through economic integration – in order to facilitate free movement of people and goods. This will create opportunities for people to move to areas with economic resources thereby benefiting from the advantages of agglomeration (Venables, 2007) thus promoting economic development and allowing for efficient allocation of resources across regions. There is, however, a negative side to the demographic argument. Population growth eats away at economic development. The rapid population growth in most African countries due to increased health care coverage and nutrition ended up drowning all the economic achievements of the 60s and 70s. To illustrate this point, between 1965 and 1980, the per capita GNP Africa grew by 3% but declined by 0.4% between 1980 and 1990. During these two periods the rate of population growth grew from 2.8% to 3% (Ohadike, 1996). Since 1980, population growth has on average outstripped economic growth, thus putting a strain on the continent’s infrastructure and contributing to the deterioration of provision of services such as healthcare and education. A high population growth rate also increases a country’s dependency ratio thereby reducing its savings rate. This has a direct negative effect on economic development because a low savings rate implies reduced investments (Debraj, 1998). While appreciating the negative effects of population growth, it still holds that sparsely populated areas do not provide the suitable ingredients needed to spur 7

Opalo economic growth. Even with a population growth rate of zero, Africa still needs a great amount of economic integration in order to increase trade and the mobility of factors of production, the latter which causes a rational and efficient allocation of the same factors. A case can also be made for the approach to developing Africa suggested in this paper based on studies of how borders impact trade. With increasing globalization, many people have come to take borders for granted. The truth, however, is that borders still matter, especially when it comes to trade. A study by John McCallum found evidence to suggest that borders actually reduce trade volumes, ceteris paribus (McCallum, 1995). The subject of the study was the US-Canadian border and how it impacted trade between the two nations. The results indicated that the mere existence of a border had a significant effect on trade patterns in the border regions of both countries. Given the good infrastructure between these two countries, it is reasonable to assume that “border induced” trade barriers would even be more acute in areas where they have been reinforced by poor or sometimes non-existent infrastructure, like is the case in Africa. Going by these findings, it is reasonable to assume that by opening up African borders would promote a growth in the volume of intra-continental trade, which currently stands at a paltry 10%7. A key ingredient of economic growth in Africa, like in most other regions, will be foreign direct investment (FDI). However, comparing historical FDI figures for both Africa and South East Asia, it becomes apparent that there is an “adverse regional effect” that makes Africa receive less FDI than other similarly underdeveloped regions, even after controlling for all other observable differences (Asiedu, 2002). This difference in FDI levels can only be attributed to the negative image the region 7

This is according to the IMF’s quarterly magazine, Development & Finance, December 2006 issue.

8

Opalo has come to acquire over the last three decades due to its reputation for violent conflicts and political mismanagement. This off-putting image can be shed off by creating economic and monetary unions. Such unions would reduce the instances of economic mismanagement and foster the formation of reputable institutions that are essential to economic growth and stability (Pevehouse, 2002). It is not just economics that necessitate economic integration in Africa; a political argument can be made for the same - in line with the liberal democratic peace arguments of International Relations theorists8. Trade promotes peace, among other associated benefits as strong institutions and proper governance. This is especially vital in violence-prone regions of Africa like the Great Lakes region and the Horn. To quote Montesquieu9, the “natural effect of commerce is to lead to peace.” Increasing interconnectedness of African nations and peoples through trade will help eliminate ethnic animosities that have fuelled numerous bloody conflicts throughout the continent.

Economic Integration: Looking at the Development Economics literature, it appears that if Africa is to develop through export orientation - the way the Asian tigers did - it will have to wait until there is a large enough differential in the cost of factors of production between the region and the new emerging markets of South East Asia and the BRICS (Brazil, Russia, India and China). It is only then that the international market will shift its gaze towards Africa which will then still have cheap labor and less restrictive 8

This is a reference to the Kantian democratic peace theory which posits that democratic nations do not go to war with each other. An extension of this is the neoliberal idea of “Complex Interdependence” advanced by Robert Keohane and Joseph Nye. Complex interdependence suggests that when countries are economically integrated through trade and by being partners in international institutions like the UN, they rarely go to war with each other because going to war with each other would lead to severe losses due to the disruption of trade links. For more information see “Power and Interdependence” by Robert Keohane and Joseph Nye (2001). 9 Charles de Secondat, Baron de Montesquieu in “Spirit of the Laws” published in 1748.

9

Opalo labor laws to facilitate a relocation of industrial production from the Pacific Rim in the same way that the shift occurred from Western Europe and the Western Offshoots10 (Collier, 2007). Obviously, the region can ill-afford to sit and wait for this eventuality. There is an urgent need for Africa, as a region, to boost its position in the world trade arena by being both inward and outward looking. Development Economics literature also point to the fact that sustainable economic growth necessarily requires industrial development, which shifts factors of production from low-level productivity areas to high-level productivity areas11. If Africa is to develop a robust industrial sector, it is imperative that it does this with a view of selling primarily to a domestic market since the global market is currently saturated by the above mentioned emerging market nations. This can only be done through economic integration, since, as mentioned above, many African countries lack the big populations needed to support a robust industrial sector.

The theory: Economic integration theory suggests that integration affects participating economies through two main channels: The scale-effect channel and the factorreallocation channel (Bretschger and Steger, 2004). Scale-effects have to do with the benefits that accrue to a region after the expansion of markets and establishment of linkages between similar or complementary firms. Factorreallocation on the other hand deals with the idea that in an integrated free market economy the market allocates capital efficiently – across sectors and/or geographical locations. Economic integration therefore increases opportunities for increased efficiency in factor-reallocation and thus ought to positively influence the

10

Western Off-shoots here refers to the United States, Canada, Australia and New Zealand. The United Nations World Economic and Social Survey, 2006. Oct. 27th 2008 11

10

Opalo rate of economic growth. While the scale effect may have an unambiguously positive effect, factor-reallocation effects are ambiguous. This is because with an expansion of markets (a case of the scale effect), production capacity can be increased or reduced depending on the demand thereby limiting any losses when shifts are necessitated by market conditions. Production factors on the other hand are not as flexible. Once a plant has been moved to a new location it is not easy to relocate because of a change in the market condition. Furthermore, it is hard to anticipate all the factors that might be in play in determining whether such a reallocation of factors of production will be profitable or not. Therefore the net effect of integration remains a coin toss. The available literature on trade growth after integration offer mixed results. Edwards (1998), Badinger (2005) and Dollar (1992) find a positive net effect in their studies of economic integration. A case study of the EU-block by Hendekson et al. (1997) also found significant positive effects. Another study of the EU-block by Frankel and Wei (1993) found that joining the block in 1980 would have increased a member country’s volume of intraregional trade by 68%. However, Vanhoudt (1999) found the net effect to be negative. Yet others studies have found the effect to remain ambiguous (Bretschger and Steger, 2004). The ambiguity of the economic integration theory can be dispelled by a look at international trade studies. Here, the findings illustrate that, in general, trade benefits all those involved – in terms of transferring technology, enhancing efficiency and promoting growth (Irwin, 2005). Same studies show that regional trade is particularly important in accelerating reforms of domestic policies that distort prices and inhibit trade thus further opening up countries to wider multilateral trade (Burfisher et al., 2001). It light of these findings, it hard to imagine that economic integration would have net negative effects 11

Opalo

Relating economic integration theory to Africa: Applying the economic theory to the African context, it is reasonable to speculate that scale effects will be unambiguously positive. Because of sparse populations and uneven distribution of natural resources, not every African country can support a vibrant industrial base. But as integrated economic regions, various parts of the continent can support industries by exploiting their comparative advantages in relation to other regions and the scale effects of having bigger markets. Economic integration would allow for free flow of capital that would shift resources from region to region depending on need and efficiency concerns. It would also provide bigger and more diverse markets for whatever industries that emerge thereafter. The development of an industrial base in Africa is of paramount importance. As already mentioned above, technological progress is the main engine of growth and such growth can only be attained and sustained through industrialization. No region of the world has managed to achieve a state of sustainable economic development without having a homegrown industrial sector. Individual African countries, with the exception of a populous few like Nigeria and South Africa, will not be able to achieve this on their own – hence the need for the creation of regional economic units. Furthermore, the historical dependence of African economies on commodity exports has proven to be a failed strategy. Over the last three decades, African commodity exporters had been victim to fluctuations in global commodity prices which have had adverse effects on their economies. A case in point is Zambia. After the Copper boom and burst of the 70s, the country suddenly found itself unable to finance projects and an expanded government from the boom years (Bevan, 1993). The adverse effect of this kind of “export instability” on economic growth has been well documented (MacBean, 1966). It is imperative therefore that 12

Opalo Africa places its bets, with regard to economic development, on local industries and markets that are relatively decoupled from the global markets to protect its economies from adverse global shocks. At this point it is necessary to look at where the region stands in global trade activity. Africa has about 12% of the world population but accounted for only 2% percent of world trade in 2005; down from about 5% in 1970 (see figure ii below). This sharply contrasts with Asia whose share has increased from about 5% to over 20% with the same period. It is also important to note that the decline in African exports has not been matched by significant increases in intra-continental trade which still stands at a paltry 10% as of 2006 (IMF, 2006). Although unrecorded intracontinental trade exists (Akello-Ogutu, 1997) and despite the encouraging evidence of growth of recorded trade (McCormick and Pedersen, 1999), there is still a pressing need to significantly increase trade activities both within the continent of Africa and with the rest of the world. The latter will be difficult, especially in line of East Asia’s domination of the global light manufactures export market. But the former can be achieved through economic integration. Such integration would open up the region to business opportunities that exist throughout the continent. A good illustration of this is the fact that retail sales in Kenya have grown by over 64% in the last four years alone.12 This suggests that there is still a huge untapped market that can be exploited for economic gains if resource mobility was enhanced in the region through economic integration. Figure (ii): Shares of Asia and Africa in world merchandise trade, 1990 -0013 Asia

12

East African Business Week, Monday 18th June, 2007. The African figures on this graph include North Africa, which is not part of the region commonly referred to as Sub-Saharan Africa. Source: World Trade Organization, 2001. 13

13

Opalo Africa

Monetary Union: Monetary union in Africa can be carried out in either one of two ways. The first option would be to have a single currency for the entire region with one independent central bank in charge of monetary policy. The second option would be to have regional blocks of currency unions like the existing CFA Zones. Possible regions would be West Africa, Central Africa, East Africa and Southern Africa. As is explained below, the latter option is better than the former. West and Central Africa have a head start because of the existing France backed CFA zones. Southern Africa (Lesotho, Namibia, Swaziland and South Africa) also has a Common Monetary Area (CMA) which is essentially a formal exchange rate union but with separate currencies, with rates fluctuating within narrow or zero margins and a strong degree of coordination between central banks. The participating countries’ currencies are linked one to one to the South African Rand (Mason and Patillo, 2005). An expansion of these three existing unions and in the case of East Africa a creation of a new union is what this paper proposes. Finance is the engine of growth. The centrality of finance in economic development is, by most accounts, undisputable. Although some scholars maintain that it is economic growth that leads to the development of complex financial institutions that efficiently allocate capital (Lucas, 1988), the majority believe that the arrow of causality run in the opposite direction (Schumpeter, 1912; Goldsmith, 1969; Miller, 1998). The bottom line, however, is that regardless of one’s belief, the importance of the financial sector in resource allocation is indubitable. An efficient financial sector removes market distortions, allowing for savings and investment rates that are 14

Opalo conducive to economic development (Demirguc-Kunt, Asli, 2006). Because of the degree of importance of the financial sector, it is important that it is run with high integrity and with regard to free-market ideals (Friedman, 1964). The integrity of any country’s financial sector can only be maintained in the presence of strong institutions devoid of political manipulations (Calvo and Mishkin, 2003). In the case of Africa, the integrity of its financial institutions has been wanting. Economic mismanagement and rent seeking activities have, many a time, led to the adoption of policies that distort the market thus causing macroeconomic instability. The historical overvaluation of African currencies is legendary (Ghura and Grennes, 1993). Decades of poor governance have stunted institutional development, with grave consequences for African economies (Chabal, 2002). Repeated attempts at reforms have been met with little enthusiasm and have largely failed (Van de Walle, 2001). Perhaps a way of instituting reform would be to take the power to effect monetary policy and regulate the different countries’ financial sectors away from individual governments and give it to regional central banks staffed with credible, apolitical experts. This can be implemented via a currency union, in the model of the European Union’s euro-zone. Having such currency unions would bring about much needed macroeconomic stability in the four regions of Africa and create confidence in the same economies. Regulation of the financial sectors would also be entrusted to these central banks in order to de-politicize the regional financial sectors and harmonize regional capital markets. The whole idea behind such unions would be to promote trade and accompanying economic development – and there is evidence to suggest that this indeed would be the case (Vickers, 2000). Vickers notes that although monetary unions do not necessarily promote growth, they serve to ensure price stability – much needed to 15

Opalo tame Africa’s runaway inflation. Furthermore, such unions instill fiscal discipline since individual governments cannot monetize deficits like they are wont to do when they control the mint. Other studies by Rose (2000) and Glick and Rose (2002) have also found that controlling for all factors (such as proximity, trade arrangements, among others) countries that use a single currency have an increased volume of trade compared to those that have their own sovereign currencies. So at the minimum, currency unions in Africa would guarantee sanity in the formulation and implementation of monetary policies and regulation of the financial sector. Beyond that, and with the right ingredients in place, there is potential for an increase in trade volume and a realization of the associated benefits of more efficient financial markets.

The theory: There is no unified theory of optimum currency areas. There are different theories that try to explain the conditions under which such arrangements can succeed and when they cannot. Based on a survey of the available literature on this subject, two types of criteria emerge for determining the success or failure of currency areas into two groups as displayed in table (i).

Table (i): Criteria for an optimum currency area Country specific criteria High flexibility in wages and prices

Region - Specific criteria High mobility of production factors

High degree of product diversification

Similar industrial structures High co-variation in economic activity Similar cultural and economic factors Similar economic policy preferences

16

Opalo

Source: Tavlas (1993) and Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1997) The country specific criteria evaluate the state of an individual country’s economy and how it would be affected by joining a currency union. Flexibility in wages and prices is important because after a country concedes the ability to use monetary tools to offset shocks to its economy, such shocks can only be offset by adjustments in the prices of goods and labor (Friedman, 1964). Rigid labor laws and/or sticky prices are therefore inimical to success after a country joins a currency area. A high degree of product diversification is also important for hedging purposes. A country that is asymmetrically dependent on one industry or commodity would suffer greater consequences from external shocks once it joins a currency union more than it would if it had a diverse basket of products. Region-specific criteria deal with the currency area as a whole and the factors that may increase the chances of success of such a union. High mobility of production factors is essential because it guarantees efficient use of these factors. In other words it guarantees that capital and labor move to areas where they are most needed and would be used the most efficiently. Similarity in industrial structures ensures uniformity and standardization. This is most essential when one considers infrastructure designs such as railway gauges, electricity grid, among other things. Perhaps the most important ingredient for success in a currency area is the need for covariance in economic activity. Countries experiencing different business cycles and which experience different types of shocks ill-fit in a currency union. This is so because it makes it hard for the affected countries to uniformly implement the necessary monetary adjustments that might be needed to offset any shocks that may affect the economy (Chamie, De Serres and Lalonde, 1994). This is the reason for this paper’s recommendation that currency unions in Africa be implemented 17

Opalo along regional lines. Similarity in culture and economic factors is important because of the significance of the interplay between culture and economic outcomes. Using proxies for culture – like religion, structure of social relations, among others - various studies conducted in areas as diverse as Economics and Anthropology have since discovered that there is a correlation between culture and economic outcomes of any given people (Guiso and Zingales, 2006; Stulz and Williamson, 2002). Similarity in economic policy preferences is an obvious requirement in a currency union. Participating countries must commit to agreed levels of government deficit and ways of financing those deficits, among other things.

Relating the optimum currency area theories to Africa: Applying the above criteria to the African situation reveals various challenges. To begin with, the labour market in Africa is not flexible. This is illustrated by the higher than normal wages in the formal sector, despite the fact that the countries in this region usually have high unemployment rates (Kingdon, Sandefur and Teal, 2006). This condition, according to optimal currency area theory, makes the region unsuitable for a currency union since it makes it harder for states to correct disequilibria due to country-specific shocks after ceding foreign exchange rate adjustment as a policy tool (Monga 1997). On the diversification criterion, Africa also scores poorly. The region’s economies have largely remained dependent on the primary production industries of agriculture and mining. That said, it is important to note that this theoretical criterion considers differential levels of diversification. This means that what matters is relative diversification; how country A is diversified relative to other countries around it. In a union with only a few highly diversified countries, the less diversified countries would suffer as the more developed 18

Opalo economies establish monopolies over entire sectors of the economy. But the African situation is not like this. Nearly all the economies in the region have the same levels of diversification and so would all benefit from a currency union, as predicted by the theoretical assumptions stated above. Judging by Africa’s history, the region-specific criteria are going to be the hardest to meet because of their dependence on political will. However, there is hope for positive outcomes in the newly created African Union. The charter of the Union has revolutionary ideas concerning economic and cultural integration of the continent. Gaddafi’s empty rhetoric of a United States of Africa aside, the region should consider quick implementation of the trade and labor mobility proposals in its constitutive act14. This would remove most of the barriers to free movement of factors of production across borders thereby reducing the effects of any asymmetric shocks within the currency unions. Once such openness to trade and production factor mobility is in place there will then be a need to harmonize economic policies in the various regions that form the unions. The African currency unions would not find it difficult meeting the criterion for similar industrial structures. As stated above, most of Africa’s economies are extractive and in the beginning stages development. States forming the currency unions would therefore simply have to harmonize their development agenda in order to ensure an outcome with relatively similar industrial structures. Because of their underdeveloped and extractive nature, the economies of Africa have had a significant degree of co-variation, depending on global commodity prices. This situation would persist even during integration and thus obviate the need for autonomous exchange rate adjustments because shocks would be similar across the board. On the need for similar cultures and economic factors, the regions, although 14

The African Union Constitutive Act: http://www.au2002.gov.za/docs/key_oau/au_act.htm

19

Opalo diverse in their own unique ways, still have a great amount of resemblance in terms of cultural practices and economic activities – mainly revolving around subsistence farming and animal husbandry. Therefore, transforming the regions’ economies while at the same time maintaining these similarities, under currency unions, should not pose any serious difficulties. The last union-specific requirement, being political, will pose greater challenges. African countries are not known for their excellent policy preferences. Policy preferences in the region tend to depend on domestic political contingencies rather than sound economic principles (Dollar and Easterly, 1999). The solution to this problem would have to be political – leaders realizing that printing money for elections and/or artificially inflating currency prices are not good for long term growth and development. Furthermore, countries with different histories of inflation will find it hard to converge to the regional desired rate without bold policy measures (Jonung and Sjoholm, 1999). As already pointed out, there is no reason to completely rule out the possibility of African leaders cooperating in this respect, especially in light of the new treaty of the African Union. Currency unions would implicitly force member states to adopt similar policies thus reducing chances of manipulation of monetary policy by individual countries for political ends. While most of the arguments presented here in relating of the optimum currency areas theory to the African condition have not been backed up by raw data, it is fairly reasonable to assume that the findings on the ground would not grossly contradict the conclusions made in the preceding paragraphs. Indeed, there is empirical evidence from CFA Franc zones in central and West Africa that suggests that with the proper institutions in place the proposals presented in this paper can work. For instance, the CFA Franc Zones have had historically lower inflation rates 20

Opalo compared to the rest of the continent due to policy restrictions imposed on member states by virtue of being in the two currency unions (Honohan, 1990). The rest of Africa can learn from the existent weaknesses of these two currency zones - which have mainly been adverse incentives and a great amount of moral hazard caused by weak central banks and France’s guarantee to back the CFA Franc (Fuouda and Stasavage, 2000). Building on the strengths of the CFA zones, new currency unions should be created with an express commitment to support strong institutions and economically sound monetary policies. Potential Challenges: The advantages of economic integration far outweigh any disadvantages that may result from coupling of economies or trade diversion (Burfisher, et al., 2001). Free trade benefits all those engaging in it. It allows for the transfer of technology, labor and capital mobility and increases competition leading to greater efficiency. African leaders ought to place a premium on potential for continental economic expansion and growth. As has been noted above, sustained economic development is only attainable if a country or economic region has an industrial base and potential for technological advancement. Reliance on the export of raw materials will not only fail at promoting economic growth, it is also bad for the development of transparent government and reliable institutions (Karl, 1997; Sachs and Warner, 1995; Shafer, 1994). Africa’s economic development, just like that of the Asian tigers, will be heavily dependent on foreign direct investment (FDI). There is evidenceto suggest that economic integration attracts FDI more than stand alone economies, even in advanced regions of the world (Brenton, Di Mauro and Lucke, 1999). Economic integration will not only help the region shed some of its bad image, but will also help it attract much needed investment to create jobs and develop industry. But FDI 21

Opalo alone will not do the trick. The continent has to boost local investment and savings rates. It is estimated that the amount of capital flight from the continent between the years 1970 – 1996 was a whooping US $ 176 billion (Ndikumana and Boyce, 2002). Couple this with the fact that as of 2002 there were over 100,000 African millionaires worth over US $ 600 billion15 and it becomes clear that it is possible for domestic investment to play a role in getting the continent of Africa out of the economic ditch that it finds itself in right now. The biggest challenge will be how to implement the currency unions. First of all, this paper proposes that there be four unions – Southern Africa, East Africa, Central Africa and West Africa. The idea of having a monetary union raises serious questions about monetary policy and adjustment to shocks. Optimality of currencies, even within individual states cannot be taken for granted. Different regions have different economic structures and may experience different shocks (Mundell, 1961). Furthermore, labor and capital mobility is not guaranteed, even within borders. These challenges get even more amplified when one considers entire regions of a continent as big as Africa. The counterpoint to this challenge is that the reduction in transaction costs and liquidity security provided by the use of a single currency within a country or within regions far outweighs the disadvantages of being in a single currency area. To add to this is the fact that less developed countries, in light of the large size of their informal economies usually have more labor and price flexibility than official figures that only capture formal employment may suggest (Calvo and Mishkin, 2003). The bottom line is that there can never be objective optimality of a single currency, even within nation states. It is all a question of weighing the pros and cons. In the African case, the advantages of having currency unions, as argued here, would outweigh the disadvantages. 15

African Business (London), Sept. 2004, p. 8. 22

Opalo The other disadvantage of being in an optimum currency area is the fact that individual countries would lose their powers to use monetary policy to offset nominal or real shocks on their economies. In the African case, the lack of this policy option might actually be a good thing. The need for monetary policy flexibility assumes that governments choose to use exchange rate policy as an instrument only when warranted by economic concerns (Eichengreen, 1994). However, empirical evidence, mostly from Africa, has shown that political instability greatly increases the likelihood of abuse of this policy instrument (Klein and Marion, 1994). Because of this, it would overall be beneficial for the countries in the region to cede control of their monetary policy to an independent and reputable regional central bank in a currency union (Fouda and Stasavage, 2000) than to leave this tool in the hands of politicians. It goes without mention that institutional strength is vital to the success of currency unions. Africa’s institutional weaknesses may hinder the establishment of robust financial institutions to accommodate the levels of economic and monetary integration advocated for in this paper. Indeed, some might even argue that the choice of having a currency union should be secondary to the development of sound financial institutions that have credibility to guarantee to stability of a country’s financial sector (Calvo and Mishkin, 2003). To counter this challenge, it is important to note that being in a currency union offers institutional stability or a bias towards institutional stability because of potential for stricter oversight by players with a lot of power and leverage – nation states. Being international institutions, the central bank in the currency unions would be less susceptible to political manipulation compared to individual states’ central banks.

23

Opalo Lacking in the arguments presented in this paper are the already existing preferential trade area arrangements – Economic Community of West African States (ECOWAS), the East Africa Community (EAC) or the Southern Africa n Development Community (SADC). This is deliberate because these regional arrangements, as currently constituted, have not managed to spur significant amounts of trade and economic development (Geda and Kebret, 2007). Many of the regional economic agreements unnecessarily overlap, thus creating complications than are needed when trying to promote free trade (Foroutan and Pritchett, 1993). A case in point is the SADC. A study found that even though the South African economy is much larger than of any other country in the Southern African region, it is not big enough to act as a growth pole for the region (Lewis, Robinson and Thierfelder, 1999). For these regional arrangements to succeed there is the need for a deliberate attempt to integrate the participating economies rather than leave this task to market forces. Another facet of the African development discourse lacking in this paper is the role of Overseas Development Assistance (ODA). This is deliberate because so far there is no evidence of significant ODA success in Africa. Since the sixties the continent has received the equivalent of six Marshall Plans (Taylor, 2005). If ODA were an essential part of economic development then Africa would be far mode developed than it currently is. ODA may be helpful in the short term – for financing deficits and essential programs like healthcare – but in the long run it undermines development because it encourages a culture of dependency and undermines institutions of government by making governments accountable to foreign aid givers and not the populations they govern (Knack, 2004; Bautigam and Knack, 2004; Moss, Petterson and Van de Walle, 2006). To reiterate the hackneyed phrase, what Africa needs is not aid but trade. If farm subsidies were scrapped and African farmers allowed to 24

Opalo compete freely prices of basic commodities would go up thus making farming a viable economic activity for millions of African farmers. An example is cotton, a vital commodity for the African nation of Mali. If farm subsidies were to be abolished, the global price of cotton would go up by as much as 20% thus providing much needed income and foreign reserves for this arid African country (Taylor, 2005). The current buzz in the “aid industry” is the achievement of the millennium development goals16. It is not surprising that Africa will not meet these goals (Sachs, McArthur and Schmidt-Traub, 2005). Development assistance programs, as currently constituted,cannot promote sustainable growth and development. Instead, they continue to erode institutional strength and promote dependence, as illustrated above.

Conclusion: Africa’s arbitrary borders have oftentimes been blamed for the continent’s troubles (Herbst, 2001). Adopting economic policies that are blind to these national boundaries is a way of mitigating the impact of this historical accident. This paper offers a challenge to the existing idea of statist economic development planning. Instead there ought to be regional planning. Many of Africa’s countries are landlocked. Economic development fuelled by trade with the external world and the rest of Africa in these countries is dependent on the quality of infrastructure in their neighboring countries (Collier, 2007). This calls for further integration of African economies in order for the region, as a whole, to have a harmonized development 16

The millennium development goals are a set of targets set by the Millennium Summit at the UN in 2000 with a target of eliminating a number of problems afflicting the third world by 2015. The goals include: halving global poverty levels and eliminating hunger, providing education for all children of school-going age, improving gender relations and care for the girl-child, providing dependable maternal health, combating HIV and AIDS, improving environmental conditions for sustainable development and lastly, to promote global partnerships in development. This last commitment requires the governments of the developed world to give at least 0.7% of their GDP as foreign Aid. For more details see

25

Opalo agenda. To facilitate this integration, the regions of the continent need common currencies to reduce the cost of transaction and build confidence in their economies by offering convertible currencies, guarantying sound monetary policies and enhancing the development of credible financial institutions. Economists have yet to come up with a general theory of the location of economic activity. The existing work on growth theory is founded on closed-economy models. There is a need for a new geographical economics that recognizes the fact that “dense configurations of economic activity work better than sparse or fragmented ones” and provides policy prescriptions for the creation of these high density economic clusters (Venables, 2006). Africa’s challenge is to create poles of growth, its own silicon valleys and route 128’s17. Evidence suggests that for this to occur it will need more big cities and population centers. Recent work on the relationship between population densities and productivity suggests that doubling the size of a city/population center is associated with a productivity increase of 3 percent to 8 percent (Rosenthal and Strange, 2004). To benefit from the economic advantages of agglomeration, Africa needs increased labor mobility within and across countries on the continent. Although the role of a development-oriented industrial policy in economic growth remains controversial (Rodrik, 2004), Africa needs policies that encourage both domestic and foreign direct investment in creating a domestic industrial base. These policies ought to support the development of credible institutions, low transaction costs, economic factor mobility and convertible currencies. All these are achievable through having integrated economies and currency unions in the different regions of the continent. This paper concludes with a recommendation for further research on economic integration and monetary unions 17

This is a reference to the technology hub in Silicon Valley, California and the Route 128 biotechnology corridor in Massachusetts.

26

Opalo in the various regions of the continent of Africa. The dearth of data to support some of the arguments presented here is because of the little scholarly interest in this particular area of Development Economics.

References: Achebe, Chinua. The trouble with Nigeria. Enugu, Nigeria: Fourth Dimension, 1985. Akello-Ogutu, C. “Unrecorded cross-border trade between Kenyan and Uganda: Implications for food security.” Bureau for Africa, USAID. Technical Paper No. 59. Washington, DC (1997). Amjadi, A., U. Reincke and A.J. Yeats. “Did External Barriers Cause the Marginalization of Sub-Saharan African in World Trade?” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 1586, Washington DC: Work Bank. 1996 Apollos, Machira. “Ethnicity, Violence and Democracy.” Africa Development. Vol. 25, 1 & 2 (2001) Asiedu, Elizabeth. “On the determinants of foreign direct investment in developing countries: is Africa different?” World Development. Vol.30, No.1 (2002): 107-119. Badinger, Herald. “Growth effects of economic integration: evidence from the EU member states.” 27

Opalo Review of World Economics. Vol. 141 (2005): 50 – 78. Bautigam, Deborah and Stephen Knack. “Foreign Aid, Institutions and Governance in Sub-Saharan Africa.” Economic Development and Cultural Changes. 52 (2004): 255-85 Bayoumi, T. and B. Eichengreen. “Optimum currency areas and exchange rate volatility: theory and evidence compared.” International Trade and Finance: New Frontiers for Research. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997 : 184–215. Bevan, David. “Trade shocks in developing countries: Consequences and policy responses.” European Economic Review. 37 (1993): 557-65. Brenton, Paul, Francesca Di Mauro and Matthias Lucke. “Economic Integration and FDI: An Empirical Analysis of Foreign Investment in the EU and in Central and Eastern Europe.” Empirica. 26:2 (1999): 95 -121 Bretschger, L. and Steger, T. “The dynamics of economic integration: Theory and Policy.” WIF-Institute of Economic Research 32 (2004): 119-134. Boserup, Ester. Population and Technology Change: A study of long-run trends. Chicago, Ill.: University of Chicago Press, 1981. Burfisher, Mary E. et al. “The Impact of NAFTA on the United States.” Journal of Economic Perspectives. 28

Opalo Vol.15 (2001): 125 – 144 Calvo, Guillermo A., Frederic S. Mishkin. “The mirage of exchange rate regimes for emerging market countries.” Journal of Economic Perspectives. 17:4 (2003): 99-118 Chabal, Patrick. “The quest for good government and development in Africa: Is NEPAD the answer?” International Affairs.78:3 (2002): 447-62 Chamie, Nick, Alain De Serres and Rene Lalonde. “Optimum currency areas and shock asymmetry: a comparison of Europe and the United States.” Bank of Canada WP 94:1 (1994). Cleaver, Kevin M. “The impact of price and exchange rate policies on agriculture in sub-Saharan Africa” World Bank Working Papers No.728 (1985). Collier, Paul. The Bottom Billion: why the poorest countries are failing and what can be done about it. Oxford, UK.: Oxford University Press, 2007. Demirguc-Kunt, Asli. “Finance and Economic Development: Policy Choices for developing Countries.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3955 (2006). Diamond, Jared. Guns, germs, and steel: the fates of human societies. New York, NY: W.W. Norton & Company, 1997. Dollar, D. “Outward-oriented developing countries really do grow more rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs.” 29

Opalo Economic Development and Cultural Change. 40, 3 (1992): 523-544. Dollar, D. and W. Easterly. “The search for the key: Aid investment and policies in Africa.” Journal of African Economics. Vol.8, No.4(1999): 546-577. Edwards, S. “Openness, productivity and growth: What do we really know?” Economic Journal. 108 (1998): 383-398. Eichengreen, B. “International Monetary Arrangements for the 21st Century.” The Brookings Institution. (1994). Fisher, Frankel, Jeffrey and Shang-Jin Wei. “Trade Bocks and Currency Blocks.” NBER Working Paper Series No. 4335 (1993). Friedman, Milton. Essays in positive economics. Chicago, Ill.: University of Chicago Press, 1964. Foroutan, Faezeh and Lant Pritchett. “Intra-Sub-Saharan trade: is it too little.” Journal of African Economics. 2:1 (1993): 74 - 105 Fouda, S., D. Stasavage. “The CFA Franc Zone After EMU: Status Quo, Reform or Dissolution?” The World Economy. Vol. 23, Issue 2 (2000): 221-233. Geda, A. and H. Kebet. “Regional Economic Integration in Africa: A review of problems and prospects with a case study of COMESA.” Journal of African Economics. (2007).

30

Opalo Ghura, Dhaneshwar and Thomas J. Grennes. “The real exchange rate and macroeconomic performance in sub-Saharan Africa.” Journal of development Economics. 42 (1993) Glick, Reuven and Andrew K. Rose. “Does a currency union affect trade? The timeseries evidence. ” European Economic Review. 46:6 (2002): 1125 -1151 Guiso, Luigi and Luigi Zingales. “Does culture affect economic outcomes?” Center for Economic Policy Research. Discussion. Paper 5505 (2006). Henrekson, M., Torstensson, J., Torstensson, R. “Growth Effects of European Integration.” European Economic Review. 41 (1997): 1537-1557. Herbst, Jeffrey. States and Power in Africa. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2000. Honohan, P. “Price and convergence in currency unions.” World Bank. (1990) Irwin, Douglas A. Free Trade Under Fire. Princeton, NJ.: Princeton University Press, 2005. Jerome, Afeikhena. “Infrastructure in Africa: The Record.” African Development Bank Economic Research Papers. No. 46 (1999). Johnson, Michael et al.” The role of intermediate factor prices in Asia’s green revolution: lessons for Africa?” American Journal of Agricultural Economics. Vol. 85, 5 (2003): 12111216.

31

Opalo Karl, Terry Lynn. The Paradox of Plenty: Oil Booms and Petro-States. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1997 Kingdon, G., Sandefur, J., Teal, F. “Labour Market Flexibility, Wages and Incomes in Sub-Saharan Africa in the 1990s” African Development Review, Volume 18, Number 3 (2006): 392427 Klein, N. and P. Marion. “Explaining the duration of exchange rate pegs.” NBER. Working Paper No.4651 (1994). Knack, Stephen. “Does foreign aid promote democracy?” International Studies Quarterly. 48:1 (2004): 251 - 66 Kremer, Michael. “Population growth and technological change: One million BC to 1990.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 108 (1993): 681-716 Lewis, Jeffrey D., Sherman Robinson and Karen Thierfelder. “After the negotiations: assessing the impact Of free trade agreements in Southern Africa.” TMD Discussion Paper No. 46 (1999) MacBean, A. L. Export Instability and Economic Development. London, UK.: George Allen and Unwin, Ltd., 1966. Massey, D., and R.A Meegan. “The geography of industrial reorganization.” Progress in Planning. 10 32

Opalo (1979): 155-237. Masson, P. and Pattillo, C. The Monetary Geography of Africa. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution Press, 2005. McCallum, John. “National Borders Matter: Canada-U.S. Regional Trade Patterns.” The American Economic Review. Vol. 85, No. 3. (1995): 615-623. Monga, C. “A Currency Reform Index for Western and Central Africa.” The World Economy. 20,1 (1997): 103 -125. Moss, Todd, Gunilla Petterson and Nicolas van de Walle. “An Aid-Institutions Paradox? A review essay on Aid dependence and state building in Sub-Saharan Africa. ” Center for Global Development. WP 74 (2006). McCormick, D. and P. O. Pedersen. “Globalization and regionalization of Kenya’s foreign trade and production.” Centre for Development Research, Copenhagen. CDR Working Paper 99.8 (1999). Mundel, Robert A. “A theory of Optimum Currency Areas.” American Economic Review. 51:3 (1961): 657–665. Ndikumana, Leonce and James Boyce. “Public debts and private assets: explaining capital flight from

33

Opalo sub-SaharanAfrican countries.” Amherst: Political Economy Research Institute. Working Paper no. 32 (2002). Nunn, Nathan. “Historical Legacies: A model of linking Africa’s past to its current underdevelopment.” Journal of Development and Economics. 83. (2007): 157 – 175. Ohadike, Patrick O. “The African population growth and development conundrum.” Health Transition Review. Supplement to Volume 6 (1996): 325-344. Pedersen, Poul Ove. “Freight transport under globalization and its impact on Africa.” Journal of Transport Geography. 9 (2001): 85-99 Pevehouse, Jon C. “With a little help from my friends? Regional organizations and the consolidation of democracy.” American Journal of Political Science. 46:3 (2002): 611 -26. Rose, Andrew K. “One Money, One Market: Estimating the Effect of Common Currencies on Trade.” Economic Policy. (2000): 7-46 Rosenthal, S. S. and W. C. Strange. “Evidence of the Nature and Sources of Agglomeration Economies.” Hanfbook of Urban and Regional Economics. 4 (2004) Sachs, Jeffrey. “Institutions Matter, But Not for Everything.” Finance & Development. (2003): 38-41. Sachs, Jeffrey and Andrew Warner. “Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth.” Harvard

34

Opalo Institute for International Development. Development Discussion Paper no. 517a. (1995) Sachs, Jeffrey, John McArthur and Guido Schmidt-Traub. “What it will take to meet the millennium development goals.” MDG Focus. (2005) Shafer, Michael D. Winners and Losers: How Sectors Shape the Developmental Prospects of States. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994 Stulz, Rene M and Rohan Williamson. “Culture, openness and finance.” Journal of Financial Economics. 70 (2003): 313–349 Tavlas, G.S. “The ‘New’ Theory of Optimum Currency Areas.” The World Economy. 16 (1993): 663-685. Taylor, Ian. “Advice is judged by results not by intentions: why Gordon Brown is wrong about Africa.” International Affairs. 81:2 (2005): 299-310 Tilly, Charles. Coercion, Capital and European States, AD 990-1990. Cambridge, MA.: Blackwell, 1990. Thomson, Scott and Nicholas Thomson. The Baobab and the Mango Tree: Africa, the Asian tigers and the Developing World. New York, NY: St. Martin’s Press, 2000. Van de Walle, Nicolas. African Economies and the Politics of Permanent Crisis, 19791999. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press, 2001.

35

Opalo Vanhoudt, P., “Did the European Unification Induce Economic Growth? In Search of Scale Effects and Persistent Changes.” Weltwirtschaftliches Archive. 135 (1999): 193-220. Venables, Anthony J. “Shifts in Economic Geography and their Causes.” London School of Economics. (2006) Vickers, John. “Monetary Union and Economic Growth.” National Bank of Belgium. Working Paper Series. No. 10 (2000) Young, Crawford. “The end of the post-colonial state in Africa? Reflections on changing African political dynamics.” African Affairs. 103 (2004): 23-49.

36

Related Documents

Econ 325
November 2019 11
325-2
April 2020 5
Sa-325
June 2020 8
Lk1939_p301-325
June 2020 4
Anboto-325
May 2020 7